![]()
BANKS CUT WALL STREET OUT! HOW STATES CAN FINANCE THEIR OWN RECOVERYEllen Brown,
October 31st, 2009 Pouring money into the private banking system has only fixed the economy for bankers and the wealthy; it has not done much to address either the fundamental problem of unemployment or the debt trap so many Americans find themselves in. President Obama's $787 billion stimulus plan has so far failed to halt the growth of unemployment: 2.7 million jobs have been lost since the stimulus plan began. California has lost 336,400 jobs. Arizona has lost 77,300. Michigan has lost 137,300. A total of 49 states and the District of Columbia have all reported net job losses. In this dark firmament, however, one bright star shines. The sole state to actually gain jobs is an unlikely candidate for the distinction: North Dakota. North Dakota is also one of only two states expected to meet their budgets in 2010. (The other is Montana.) North Dakota is a sparsely populated state of less than 700,000 people, largely located in cold and isolated farming communities. Yet, since 2000, the state's GNP has grown 56 percent, personal income has grown 43 percent and wages have grown 34 percent. The state not only has no funding problems, but this year it has a budget surplus of $1.3 billion, the largest it has ever had. Why is North Dakota doing so well, when other states are suffering the ravages of a deepening credit crisis? Its secret may be that it has its own credit machine. North Dakota is the only state in the Union to own its own bank. The Bank of North Dakota (BND) was established by the state legislature in 1919, specifically to free farmers and small businessmen from the clutches of out-of-state bankers and railroad men. The bank's stated mission is to deliver sound financial services that promote agriculture, commerce and industry in North Dakota. The Advantages of Owning Your Own BankSo, how does owning a bank solve the state's funding problems? Isn't the state still limited to the money it has? The answer is no. Chartered banks are allowed to do something nobody else can do: They can create credit on their books simply with accounting entries, using the magic of "fractional reserve" lending. As the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas explains on its web site: "Banks actually create money when they lend it. Here's how it works: Most of a bank's loans are made to its own customers and are deposited in their checking accounts. Because the loan becomes a new deposit, just like a paycheck does, the bank ... holds a small percentage of that new amount in reserve and again lends the remainder to someone else, repeating the money-creation process many times." How many times? President Obama puts this "multiplier effect" at eight to ten. In a speech on April 14, he said: "[A]lthough there are a lot of Americans who understandably think that government money would be better spent going directly to families and businesses instead of banks - 'where's our bailout?,' they ask - the truth is that a dollar of capital in a bank can actually result in eight or ten dollars of loans to families and businesses, a multiplier effect that can ultimately lead to a faster pace of economic growth." It can, but it hasn't recently, because private banks are limited by bank capital requirements and by their for-profit business models. And that is where a state-owned bank has enormous advantages: States own huge amounts of capital, and they can think farther ahead that their quarterly profit statements, allowing them to take long-term risks. Their asset bases are not marred by oversized salaries and bonuses; they have no shareholders expecting a sizable cut, and they have not marred their books with bad derivatives bets, unmarketable collateralized debt obligations and mark-to-market accounting problems. The Bank of North Dakota (BND) is set up as a dba: "the State of North Dakota doing business as the Bank of North Dakota." Technically, that makes the capital of the state the capital of the bank. Projecting the possibilities of this arrangement to California, the State of California owns about $200 billion in real estate, has $62 billion in various investments and has $128 billion in projected 2009 revenues. Leveraged by a factor of eight, that capital base could support nearly $4 trillion in loans. To get a bank charter, specific investments would probably need to be earmarked by the state as startup capital; but the startup capital required for a typical California bank is only about $20 million. This is small potatoes for the world's eighth largest economy, and the money would not actually be "spent." It would just become bank equity, transmuting from one form of investment into another - and a lucrative investment at that. In the case of the BND, the bank's return on equity is about 25 percent. It pays a hefty dividend to the state, which is expected to exceed $60 million this year. In the last decade, the BND has turned back a third of a billion dollars to the state's general fund, offsetting taxes. California could do substantially better than that. California pays $5 billion annually just in interest on its debt. If it had its own bank, the bank could refinance its debt and return that $5 billion to the state's coffers; and it would make substantially more on money lent out. Besides capital, a bank needs "reserves," which it gets from deposits. For the BND, this too is no problem, since it has a captive deposit base. By law, the state and all its agencies must deposit their funds in the bank, which pays a competitive interest rate to the state treasurer. The bank also accepts deposits from other entities. These copious deposits can then be plowed back into the state in the form of loans. Public Banking on the Central Bank ModelThe BND's populist organizers originally conceived of the bank as a credit union-like institution that would free farmers from predatory lenders, but conservative interests later took control and suppressed these commercial lending functions. The BND is now chiefly a "bankers' bank." It acts like a central bank, with functions similar to those of a branch of the Federal Reserve. It avoids rivalry with private banks by partnering with them. Most lending is originated by a local bank. The BND then comes in to participate in the loan, share risk and buy down the interest rate. One of the BND's functions is to provide a secondary market for real estate loans, which it buys from local banks. Its residential loan portfolio is now $500 billion to $600 billion. This function has helped the state to avoid the credit crisis that afflicted Wall Street when the secondary market for loans collapsed in late 2007. Before that, investors routinely bought securitized loans (CDOs) from the banks, making room on the banks' books for more loans. But these "shadow lenders" disappeared when they realized that the derivatives called "credit default swaps" supposedly protecting their CDOs were a highly unreliable form of insurance. In North Dakota, this secondary real estate market is provided by the BND, which has invested conservatively, avoiding the speculative derivatives debacle. Other services the BND provides include guarantees for entrepreneurial startups and student loans, the purchase of municipal bonds from public institutions and a well-funded disaster loan program. When the city of Fargo was struck by a massive flood recently, the disaster fund helped the city avoid the devastation suffered by New Orleans in similar circumstances; and when North Dakota failed to meet its state budget a few years ago, the BND met the shortfall. The BND has an account with the Federal Reserve Bank, but its deposits are not insured by the FDIC. Rather, they are guaranteed by the State of North Dakota itself - a prudent move today, when the FDIC is verging on bankruptcy. The Commercial Banking Model: The Commonwealth Bank of AustraliaThe BND studiously avoids competition with private banks, but a publicly-owned bank could profitably engage in commercial lending. A successful model for that approach was the Commonwealth Bank of Australia, which served both central bank and commercial bank functions. For nearly a century, the publicly-owned Commonwealth Bank provided financing for housing, small business, and other enterprise, affording effective public competition that "kept the banks honest" and kept interest rates low. Commonwealth Bank put the needs of borrowers ahead of profits, ensuring that sound investment flows were maintained to farming and other essential areas; yet, the bank was always profitable, from 1911 until nearly the end of the century. Indeed, it seems to have been too profitable, making it a takeover target. It was simply "too good not to be privatized." The bank was sold in the 1990s for a good deal of money, but it's proponents consider it's loss as a social and economic institution to be incalculable. A State Bank of Florida?Could the sort of commercial model tested by Commonwealth Bank work today in the United States? Economist Farid Khavari thinks so. A Democratic candidate for governor of Florida, he proposes a Bank of the State of Florida (BSF) that would make loans to Floridians at much lower interest rates than they are getting now, using the magic of fractional reserve lending. He explains: "For $100 in deposits, a bank can create $900 in new money by making loans. So, the BSF can pay 6 percent for CDs, and make mortgage loans at 2 percent. For $6 per year in interest paid out, the BSF can earn $18 by lending $900 at 2 percent for mortgages." The state would earn $15,000 per $100,000 of mortgage, at a cost of about $1,700, while the homeowner would save $88,000 in interest and pay for the home 15 years sooner. "Our bank will save people about seven years of their pay over the course of 30 years, just on interest costs," says Dr. Khavari. He also proposes 6 percent credit cards and 6 percent certificates of deposit. The state could earn billions yearly on these loans, while saving hefty sums for consumers. It could also refinance its own debts and those of its municipal governments at very low interest rates. According to a German study, interest composes 30 percent to 50 percent of everything we buy. Slashing interest costs can make projects such as low-cost housing, alternative energy development, and infrastructure construction not only sustainable, but profitable for the state, while at the same time creating much-needed jobs. Written for Truthout. Featured on October 31, 2009. Ellen Brown developed her research skills as an attorney practicing civil litigation in Los Angeles. In Web of Debt, her latest book, she turns those skills to an analysis of the Federal Reserve and the money trust. She shows how this private cartel has usurped the power to create money from the people themselves, and how we the people can get it back. Her earlier books focused on the pharmaceutical cartel that gets its power from the money trust. Her eleven books include Forbidden Medicine, Natures Pharmacy (co-authored with Dr. Lynne Walker), and The Key to Ultimate Health: Non-toxic Dentistry (co-authored with Dr. Richard Hansen). Her websites are www.webofdebt.com and www.ellenbrown.com.
Its Finished
John Lanchester
Its a moment of confusion and
loathing that most of us have experienced. Youre in
a shop. Its time to pay. You reach for your purse
or wallet and take out your last note. Something about it
doesnt feel quite right. Its the wrong shape
or the wrong colour and the design is odd too and the
note just doesnt seem right and . . . By
now youve realised: oh shit! Its the dreaded
Scottish banknote! Tentatively, shyly or briskly,
brazenly, according to character you proffer the
note. One of three things then happens. If youre
lucky, the tradesperson takes the note without demur.
Unusual, but it does sometimes happen. If youre
less lucky, he or she takes the note with all the good
grace of someone accepting delivery of a four-week-dead
haddock. If youre less lucky still, he or she will
flatly refuse your money. And heres the really
annoying part: he or she would be well within his or her
rights, because Scottish banknotes are not legal tender.
Legal tender is defined as any financial
instrument which cannot be refused in settlement of a
debt. Bank of England notes are legal tender in England
and Wales, and Bank of England coins are legal tender
throughout the UK, but no paper currency is. The bizarre
fact of the matter is that Scottish banknotes are
promissory notes, with the same legal status as cheques
and debit cards. These feared and despised instruments,
whose history has long been of interest to economists,
come in three varieties from three issuing banks: the
Bank of Scotland, the Royal Bank of Scotland and the
Clydesdale Bank. Small countries with big ambitions but
few natural resources need ingenious banking systems. The
history of the Netherlands, Venice, Florence and Scotland
show this and so does the tragic recent story of
Iceland. In the 17th century, when English and
European commerce was expanding by leaps and bounds,
James Buchan wrote in Frozen Desire, the
best Scots minds felt acutely the shortage of . . .
what wed now call working capital; and Scots
promoters were at the forefront of banking schemes in
both London and Edinburgh, culminating in the foundation
of the Bank of England in 1694 and the Bank of Scotland
in 1695. The powers down south, however, came to
think or pretended to think that the Bank
of Scotland was too close to the Jacobites, and so in
1727 friends of prime minister Walpole set up the Royal
Bank of Scotland. There was more to the new bank than
Whiggish manoeuvring. During the 17th century, Scottish
investors had noticed with envy the gigantic profits
being made in trade with Asia and Africa by the English
charter companies, especially the East India Company.
They decided that they wanted a piece of the action and
in 1694 set up the Company of Scotland, which in 1695 was
granted a monopoly of Scottish trade with Africa, Asia
and the Americas. The Company then bet its shirt on a new
colony in Darien thats Panama to us
and lost.[1] The resulting
crash is estimated to have wiped out a quarter of the
liquid assets in the country, and was a powerful force in
impelling Scotland towards the 1707 Act of Union with its
larger and better capitalised neighbour to the south. The
Act of Union offered compensation to shareholders who had
been cleaned out by the collapse of the Company; a body
called the Equivalent Society was set up to look after
their interests. It was the Equivalent Society, renamed
the Equivalent Company, which a couple of decades later
decided to move into banking, and was incorporated as the
Royal Bank of Scotland. In other words, RBS had its
origins in a failed speculation, a bail-out, and a
financial crash so big it helped destroy Scotlands
status as a separate nation. Fast-forward 300 years, and RBS is
today, by the size of its assets, not just a big bank,
and not just one of the biggest companies in Europe. The
Royal Bank of Scotland, by asset size, is the biggest
company in the world. If I had to pick a single fact
which summed up the cultural gap between the City of
London and the rest of the country, it would be that one.
I have yet to meet a single person not employed in
financial services who was aware of it; I wasnt
aware of it myself. I think if I had been, there are two
questions I would have wanted answered: how did that
happen? And is it a good thing? Unfortunately, the second one is easy
to answer. During the weekend of 11-12 October last year,
the point when the British banking system teetered on the
edge of collapse (the only time in my career,
a senior banker told me, when Ive felt
genuinely frightened), RBS was in receipt of an
emergency injection of government cash, to the tune of £20
billion. This left us, the taxpayers, owning about 60 per
cent of the collapsing bank. On 26 February this year,
RBS gave a preliminary announcement of its annual results.
The bank had lost £24 billion, the largest loss in
British corporate history, and required yet more
government money to stay solvent. The new government
money, £25.5 billion, took the taxpayers share of
the bank to around 95 per cent. In addition, RBS put £302
billion of its assets into the governments Asset
Protection Scheme, a sort of insurance plan under which
the government, in return for a fee, promises to
underwrite future losses from the toxic assets (these
assets used to be worth £325 billion but their value has
already been written down). A figure of £50 billion has been
widely touted as the eventual cost of this scheme to the
government not the overall cost of it, just the
part of it belonging to RBS. That figure is guesswork,
since the whole problem is that nobody knows what these
assets are worth. In the same week that news came out, it
emerged that the former chief executive of RBS, Sir Fred
Goodwin, had, at the time of the October bail-out, asked
for and received a doubling of his pension pot before he
would agree to leave the bank. This took his pension pot
to £16 million, which will pay out £693,000 annually
for life. Why did the government go to such lengths to
secure Sir Freds acceptance of his own departure,
rather than just sacking him? Why did they agree to the
doubling of his pension pot? We dont know, but
its almost certainly because, when the deal was
done, everyone was so preoccupied by the question of
whether the British banks would stay solvent that Sir
Freds pension was the last thing on anybodys
mind. Anybodys, that is, except Sir Freds. Hes an easy man to dislike. Even
his face, pinched and complacent, is easy to dislike. In
a wider perspective, however, the pension question is
something of a non-story. We are exposed to such gigantic
losses through the financial crisis that it doesnt
really matter if Sir Fred spends the rest of his life
bathing in Cristal at our expense. The question of his
pension has become a synecdoche for the more general
issue of City bonuses, which to the City are a normal
fact of life but to outsiders are the emblem of the
Citys greed and amoral exceptionalism. Its
interesting to observe how completely the banking
industry fails to hear its own tone of voice on this
subject. By City standards, Sir Freds pension is
not outlandishly large; bonuses are so much a part of
City culture on average, they make up 60 per cent
of an investment bankers pay that they are
often guaranteed by contract, and even when they
arent they are part of an employees
reasonable expectation in terms of pay, and
are therefore protected by law. To outsiders, it
doesnt make sense to have a guaranteed
bonus: if your bonus is guaranteed, it isnt a
bonus, its a salary. In the interests of preserving
their trades reputation, its bankers who
should be leading the attack on Sir Freds clearly
indefensible pension; instead, theyre chirruping
about the evils of banker bashing. To sum up: so far taxpayers have spent
£45.5 billion in directly bailing out RBS (for wonks,
thats £15 billion in equity and £5 billion in
preference shares last October, followed by £25.5
billion in capital instruments this February), plus
another £50 billion for the toxic assets in the
protection scheme (though as Ive said, thats
a plucked-out figure which could go as high as £302
billion if the assets are worthless). Call it £95.5
billion. Oh, and another £16 million to keep the person
responsible in Dom Pérignon and Charvet shirts for the
rest of his life. Still, lets look on the bright
side: at least we have an unequivocal answer to our
question about whether it was a good thing that RBS got
to be the biggest company in the world. The question of how it got to that
point is easy to answer at the macro level. RBS grew
through takeovers. These are commonplace in the financial
service industries, though it should be noticed that
takeovers and mergers often have the effect, in the long
term, of destroying value. Company A, worth £10 billion,
takes over company B, worth £5 billion, some time passes,
and you end up with a new company worth not A + B = £15
billion, but A + B = £12 billion. You have magically
made £3 billion go away. Thats destroying value,
and many takeovers and mergers in time end up doing
exactly that. Perhaps the definitive example was that of
the car companies Daimler-Benz and Chrysler. The German
company took over the American firm in 1998 at a cost of
$36 billion, promising all sorts of exciting synergies
and possibilities for growth. These turned out not to
exist, and Daimler-Benz ended up selling Chrysler in 2007
in a complicated deal which involved a net cash outflow
of 500 million an amazing turnaround and a
heroically effective destruction of value. In fact, when
you look into the question, you soon conclude that non-capitalists
and anti-capitalists should throw street parties every
time the words merger or takeover
are used. Why do they go on happening? Mainly because it
is the mission of most companies to grow, and takeovers
are one of the quickest and most spectacular ways of
doing that. This is partly a question of accounting.
In the stock market, all money is not created equal. The
price of a share is determined by what people think
its worth obviously. But what people think
its worth is in turn decided by what they think the
companys prospects are. Take the example of
companies A and B mentioned above. Both of them make
widgets. Company A is a fast-growing internet-based firm,
eWidget, which is promising to take over the world market
in widgets by riding the new trend for firms and
customers to order their widgets online. Last year its
earnings were £200 million. The companys pitch to
the stock market runs something like this: the global
market for widgets is £1 trillion. In time, say ten
years, it is clear that 30 per cent of widgets will be
ordered over the internet. Our ambition is to win 10 per
cent of that market. (The trick is to keep these
projected and made-up figures sounding sensible and
achievable: dont claim that the net will be all the
market, and that youll get all of that business.
State a huge number for the total market, and claim to be
after a sensible fraction of it.) So your sensible and
achievable goal is for eWidget to have 10 per cent of 30
per cent of £1 trillion, in other words £30 billion a
year. Wow! Its clear that eWidget has a big, big
future, and if you get in on it now by buying a piece of
the company i.e. by buying shares you will,
in time, make out like a bandit. As a result,
eWidgets shares trade at a high price in relation
to the companys present earnings: at the already
mentioned market capitalisation of £10 billion, that
means the shares cost 50 times the companys
earnings. The P/E ratio, as its called, is 50/1.
That is high, and it can only be justified by steeply
rising future growth. Company B is Goodwidget Ltd. This is a
well-run old firm with members of the original founding
family still in charge. It has grown at 10 per cent a
year for decades, and its business model is the same one
it had during those years, one of steady incremental
growth through the old-fashioned method of making a
better widget than its competitors. The stock market
takes one look at its figures and reacts with a colossal,
neck-ricking yawn. There is no glamorous upside here and
no reason to believe in any growth beyond the kind that
Goodwidget has proved it can achieve. Thus, although
Goodwidget actually sells more widgets and makes more
money than eWidget it made £500 million last year
because it seems to have less potential for growth,
its shares are, in terms of their earnings, cheaper. The
shares are priced at ten times their earnings, giving the
company a market capitalisation of £5 billion.
Goodwidget, despite earning more than twice as much as
eWidget, is worth only half as much on the stock market.
All money is not created equal. The money earned by
Goodwidget is worth much less than the money earned by
eWidget. This is one of those points of stock-market
logic which seems surreal, nonsensical and wholly
counterintuitive to civilians, but which to market
participants is as familiar as beans on toast. (An
example: when AOL took over Time Warner, the old media
company supplied 70 per cent of the profit-stream, but
ended up with 45 per cent of the merged firm, because
AOLs market cap was so much bigger. How
successfully did that play out? Well, at the time of the
merger, the new combined companys market
capitalisation was $350 billion. Today its $28.8
billion. Thats $321.2 billion in value gone with
the wind. I say again, for anti-capitalists, merger =
fiesta.) Now lets consider what happens if
eWidget takes over Goodwidget. They bid £5 billion for
the old-school company, and their offer is accepted. (In
practice, by the way, they would offer more than that,
since the whole point of takeovers is that the buyer sees
more value in the target company than the market does: he
sees a way of making more money than is already being
made. But lets keep this example simple.) The new
company is worth £10 billion plus £5 billion, yes? No
and this, from the stock markets point of
view, is the beautiful part. Goodwidgets £500
million of earnings are now added to the total revenue of
eWidget, so the merged firm is earning £700 million a
year. Remember that eWidget is valued at 50 times its
earnings (so that £700 million of earnings implies a
market capitalisation of £35 billion), which means that
eWidget shares are about to more than treble in price.
That in turn completely justifies the confidence of the
shareholders who bought a piece of this exciting, sexy,
go-go 21st-century widget-maker. The successful takeover
has magically sent the share-price rocketing; the company
has grown. It isnt whats known as
organic growth, of course, the kind which
comes from selling more of your stuff to more people, but
so what? Although most takeovers and mergers end by
destroying value, the market loves them anyway. Back to RBS. The bank fought off three
takeover/mergers in the 1970s and 1980s one each
from Lloyds, Standard Chartered and HSBC before
growing stronger and launching takeovers of its own. The
first was of Citizens Financial Group, which has grown (through
the takeover of Charter One Bank) to be the eighth
largest bank in America. The biggie, however, was the
battle to take over the high street behemoth NatWest in
1999. RBSs opponent in that battle was its old
enemy, the Bank of Scotland; the older banks plan
had been to part-fund their acquisition by selling off
various components of NatWest such as Coutts and the
Ulster Bank. (Coutts is the posh bank, concentrating
exclusively on high net-worth customers, which only
recently began issuing cheque cards. Before that, any
shop or service provider who didnt understand what
a Coutts account meant was demonstrably too lower-class
to deserve patronage from Coutts clients such as the
queen and Wayne Rooney.) RBS by contrast planned to keep
the subsidiaries together as part of a new company, the
Royal Bank of Scotland Group. RBS won the fight, and
became the second biggest UK bank after HSBC. Fred
Goodwin was something of a hero in the banking world.
Philip Delves Broughton, a former Telegraph
journalist who went to Harvard to do an MBA and wrote a
funny, depressing book about it, What They Teach You
at Harvard Business School, reports that in 2003 the
school made RBS the subject of one of its famous case
studies. The study was called The Royal Bank of
Scotland: Masters of Integration and began with a
quote from the man we now know as Fred the Shred or the
Worlds Worst Banker: Hard work, focus,
discipline and concentrating on what our customers need.
Its quite a simple formula really, but weve
just been very, very consistent with it. Right. By
now RBS, or the RBS Group, was a truly huge company,
embracing the banking interests already mentioned plus a
large range of insurance products, known to the UK
consumer under various brand names such as Direct Line,
Churchill and Privilege. From this springboard which
included a 10 per cent share in the Bank of China, the
worlds fifth biggest bank RBS launched yet
another takeover bid, this time for the Dutch bank ABN
Amro. The French philosopher René Girard talks about
something called mimetic desire, which
basically means copying our idea of what we want from
someone else who wanted it first. Were all familiar
with the phenomenon in everyday life, but RBS seems to
have had a corporate version of mimetic desire. Barclays
had launched a high-profile takeover bid for ABN Amro, a
long-established bank whose earnings and share price had
recently stagnated. (ABN stands for Algemene Bank
Nederland, the inheritors of a business which had
originally been one of the Dutch charter companies, the
Nederlandsche Handel-Maatschappij or Dutch Trading
Company not so different from RBSs legacy as
the Company of Scotland.) RBS, seeing Barclays putting
the moves on ABN Amro, decided to make some moves of its
own, and after a complicated fight, ended up winning ABN
Amro, as part of a consortium of bidders with the Belgo-Dutch
bank Fortis and the Spanish Banco Santander. The
consortium bid 71 billion, as opposed to
Barclayss 66 billion and this
notwithstanding the fact that ABN had sold off its
American subsidiary LaSalle, which was one of RBSs
reasons for being interested in the deal in the first
place. (The action of selling off LaSalle was part of
whats known in the city as a poison
pill defence, undertaking an action intended to
make you toxic to a potential predator.) The consortiums plan was to split
ABN Amro up, with RBS getting the Anglo-American and
wholesale parts of the business, Fortis the Belgo-Dutch,
and Banco Santander the South American. It wasnt in
principle a ridiculous scheme, but the problem was the
price. Most of what has been written about the financial
crisis is pure hindsight, but not this: many observers
thought that the winning consortium had overpaid. The
consortium won their takeover on 10 October 2007; by
April 2008, RBS was going to the markets to raise more
capital, to cover losses from the deal; by July 2008,
Fortis had lost two-thirds of its value and its CEO, Jean-Paul
Votron, had resigned; on 28 September, Fortis was part-nationalised
by the Dutch, Belgian and Luxembourgeois governments.
Weve already read what happened to RBS. So within
months, the ABN Amro takeover destroyed RBS and Fortis
and what was left of ABN Amro itself. Along with the AOL-Time
Warner merger and the Daimler-Chrysler merger, the ABN
Amro takeover is one of the biggest flops in corporate
history. All of this makes RBSs corporate
report for 2007, published just weeks before the bank had
to go back to the markets for more capital, a document of
unusual interest. Northrop Frye somewhere defines
irony as involving a state of affairs in
which words have a different meaning from their apparent
sense. This can be achieved by the audiences
knowing something the speaker doesnt: so the
speaker is saying one thing but we are understanding
another. The RBS corporate report is like that. (So are
their slogans: Make it happen. Make what
happen? A £100 billion tab for the taxpayer?) The
section on corporate citizenship at the beginning is
particularly good value. The firm is involved in plans to
increase general levels of financial education.
When people have been educated about money and how
to work with financial services firms they are more
likely to make the right decisions and to avoid
difficulties. Thats true, but you can also
just rob post offices. RBS is a responsible company.
We carry out rigorous research so that we can be
confident we know the issues that are most important to
our stakeholders and we take practical steps to respond
to what they tell us. Then occasionally, we blow all that
shit off, fire up some crystal meth, and throw money
around with such crazed abandon that it helps destroy the
public finances of the worlds fifth biggest economy.
See if you can guess which of those sentences is not in
the report. Joking apart, the RBS Group corporate
report is a document of historic importance. This was the
last bulletin from the bank before it blew up: a process
that began within days of its publication the
accounts were signed on 27 February 2008, and on 22 April
RBS announced that it was attempting to raise £12
billion of capital in the form of newly issued shares, to
cover its losses from the acquisition of ABN Amro. The
consequences of the banks unravelling will be with
us for a long time, in the most basic way: we will be
paying for it. Not metaphorically, but literally: instead
of schools and medicines and roads and libraries, huge
chunks of public money will go to RBSs balance
sheet. So its worth taking a close look at that
balance sheet, and before we do so, its worth
thinking for a moment about what a balance sheet actually
is. If the Titanic is the most abused metaphor
in the world in the words of the Onion
parody headline for 1912, Worlds Largest
Metaphor Hits Iceberg the balance sheet runs
it a close second. We dont know who invented balance
sheets; they seem to have been in use in Venice as early
as the 13th century. But we do know who noted down the
method behind them, and in the process invented modern
accounting, which relies on four financial statements to
provide a full picture of any given business: the balance
sheet, the income statement, the cash-flow statement, and
the statement of retained earnings. The man who noted
down the method for gathering and recording the relevant
information was Luca Pacioli, a Franciscan monk and
friend of both Piero della Francesca and Leonardo da
Vinci, whose assistant he was for many years. Pacioli
wrote Summa de Arithmetica, the book which laid
out the method of double-entry bookkeeping which is still
in use in more or less every business in the world. (He
also wrote about magic, in the sense of conjuring.
Id like to think he would have enjoyed the old joke
about accountants: Whats two plus two?
What would you like it to be?) Theres
something amazing about the fact that a method used in
Venice in the 13th century and written down by a Tuscan
in the 15th should still be in daily use in every
financial enterprise in the developed world. Of the four financial statements, the
balance sheet is the one which provides a glimpse into a
moment in time. The others show processes, flows of money;
the balance sheet is a snapshot. A balance sheet is
divided into assets and liabilities. Assets are things
which belong to you, liabilities are things which belong
to other people. Heres what an individuals
balance sheet might look like:
Youll notice there is something
mysterious on there called equity. This is
the magic ingredient which means that a balance sheet
always balances: it is added to your liabilities so that
they match your assets. The fact that it appears with the
liabilities might make equity seem sinister, but it
isnt: its a good thing. Its the amount
by which you are in the clear; its the amount by
which your assets exceed your liabilities. Your equity is
your safety margin; it is your net worth, it is the thing
which keeps you in business. Now imagine for a moment that you are a
business. Instead of just being plain you, you are now
You Ltd. You set out to sell shares in yourself. The part
of you that you sell shares in is the equity. The buyer
isnt taking over the assets and liabilities, but
the equity. Say I bought 10 per cent of your equity, as
set out in the balance sheet above, at a price of £1000
(an accurate price, since thats exactly what
its worth today). In a years time, say
youve paid back £10,000 of your mortgage, your
house price has gone up by half, youre being paid
better at work and so youve another £10,000 in the
bank golly, your assets are now £270,000, your
liabilities are £130,000 and your equity is now £140,000.
My one-tenth share of your equity is now worth £14,000.
Cool. I could sell my share in your equity and make a
nice profit, or I could just sit on it, betting that you
would do even better in the future. On the other, scarier
hand, you could have had a lousy year: your house price
might have crashed (in fact, using UK average figures,
your house price has crashed, by £50,000), you have been
put on part-time work so your salary has halved and wiped
out your savings, your debtors have gone bankrupt and
your car has lost 50 per cent of its value, so your
assets have gone down by £70,000. Your liabilities, on
the other hand, are the same. Theres a problem:
your liabilities now exceed your assets, by a cool £60,000.
In plain English, youre broke. In the language of
accountancy, you are insolvent. You have met one of the
two criteria for insolvency: your liabilities are greater
than your assets. The other criterion is inability to
meet your debts as they fall due. In British law, meeting
either criterion makes you insolvent. It is a criminal
offence to trade while insolvent. There may be a get-out, however. Are
you really insolvent? Ive made things clear-cut for
the purposes of this example, but you could argue
and in comparable cases people do argue that your
problem is not so much insolvency as illiquidity.
Liquidity is the ability to turn assets into something
that can be bought or sold. With a depressed housing
market, the problem with your house could easily be not
so much its value, as the fact that you cant sell
it, because nobody is buying property at the moment. Or
rather you can sell it, but you have to do so for an
artificially depressed, crazy-cheap price: a fire
sale price. When the market returns to normal
functioning, you will be able to sell your house for its
true value; so you arent really insolvent,
youre just caught in a liquidity trap.
In practice, all you would do, in the above example
as long as you werent really You Ltd, in
which case you might well be under a legal obligation to
go into receivership would be to simply ignore the
question and keep going. Youd hope to be able to
pay bills as they fell due, and hang on for grim life
until your house price recovered. As we speak, hundreds
of thousands of people across the UK across the
world are doing precisely that. The same principles apply to company
balance sheets. They look a lot more complicated, but the
underlying factors are the same. At business schools,
they play a game sorry, undertake an
exercise in which students are given balance
sheets and asked to determine what type of business the
company is in. Sums are in millions of pounds. So
whats the business whose balance sheet is shown
here?
There are clues in the fact that
Deposits by banks and Customer
accounts are listed in the column for liabilities.
Loans and advances are a main category of
asset. Our hypothetical business student would be able to
work out in pretty short order that this business is a
bank. Which one? A clue is the figure for Total
assets: £1,900,519,000,000 £1.9 trillion.
Since the entire GDP of the United Kingdom is £1.762
trillion, this is a freakishly large bank oh, all
right, Ill stop being coy, its our old friend
the Royal Bank of Scotland, a.k.a. the biggest company in
the world. It seems weird at first glance, and indeed at
second glance, that bank balance sheets list customer
deposits as liabilities, but it makes sense if you think
about it, since a liability is at heart something that
belongs to somebody else, and the customers
deposits belong to the customers. This was something that
my father, who worked for a bank, used often to say to me:
dont forget that if you have money in a bank
account, youre lending the bank money. Banks themselves certainly dont
forget it. Actually, thats not true. They forget it
all the time in their actual dealings with their customer/creditors
us. They act as if its their money and they
are doing us a favour by letting it sit in their bank
earning interest. Take a look at the balance sheet,
however, and at the page after page of corporate reports
and footnotes which accompany it, and its a
different story. High levels of deposits mean high levels
of liabilities; and high levels of liabilities oblige a
bank to have high levels of assets. Since banks are
mainly in the business of lending money, high levels of
assets mean high levels of loans. That means that a
banks main assets are other peoples debts.
This is another distinctive feature of bank balance
sheets, the fact that its principal assets are other
peoples debts to it. The balance sheets of other businesses
look very different. Theyre smaller, for a start:
only banks are this bloated with assets and liabilities.
Thats natural, since the business model of banking,
involving lots of money coming in and sitting in accounts,
balanced by lots of lending, is always going to involve
lots of money on the balance sheet and relatively small
amounts of equity. A company with a quicker turnover will
look very different. Apple Computer, for instance, in
2008 had $39.6 billion in assets, $18.5 billion in
liabilities and $21.1 billion in equity; compare that to
RBSs £1900 billion, £1809 billion and £91
billion. Apples assets are a fiftieth the size of
RBSs, but its equity is only a sixth the size. In
that sense, Apple is a safer business than RBS; it has a
larger safety cushion, a proportionately bigger margin
for error.[2] Of course, it
might be that it has a bigger margin for error because it
is an inherently riskier business. Banking should be much
more solid than computers/gadgets/music, but the fact
that banks will always have elephantine balance sheets,
in proportion to their equity, means they have a tendency
to be a little less secure than they look at first glance.
Thats one of the many reasons banks are, in their
corporate body-language, so keen to look as imposing and
rock-like as they possibly can. Apples accounts are all about how
many computers and phones and songs the company will sell,
since its financial health depends on that. (I say
songs Apples iTunes is the
biggest music retailer in both the UK and US.) RBSs
accounts are all about its loans, since the financial
health of the company depends on the quality of those
loans. It follows from that that RBSs accounts are
all about loan risk, since the profitability of the loans
depends on how likely they are to be repaid. For that
reason the nature of the assets the loans
are all important; and risk is not some marginal factor
but the core of a banks business. Risk is always an
important issue for any company, but for a bank, it
isnt just important, its their whole business.
Banking does not just involve the management of risk;
banking is the management of risk. The RBS accounts were signed on 27
February 2008. On 22 April, the bank went back to the
markets to seek £12 billion in new capital, to repair
its balance sheet. The later unravelling of this very
balance sheet, as Ive already said, has us on the
hook to the tune of £100 billion and maybe more. By
rights, by logic, and by everything thats holy, it
should therefore be possible to see, somewhere in the
accounts and the balance sheet, some clue to what went
wrong especially given that whatever went wrong
must have already gone wrong, to hit the company so hard
less than two months later. The reader who thinks that is
quickly disillusioned. Instead we get this: It is
the Groups policy to maintain a strong capital base,
to expand it as appropriate and to utilise it efficiently
throughout its activities to optimise the return to
shareholders while maintaining a prudent relationship
between the capital base and the underlying risks of the
business. Where on the balance sheet are the
gigantic bets that went bad? Where are all the toxic
assets? The losses were so huge that one shouldnt
have to look for them in this way in fact
its bizarre to be doing so, minutely parsing the
accounts for evidence of a gigantic disaster. Its a
little like being Sherlock Holmes, crouched over and
peering through his magnifying glass, looking for a
smoking crater the size of Birmingham. Eventually you
come across this glimmer of a clue: Derivatives,
assets and liabilities increased reflecting the
acquisition of ABN Amro, growth in trading volumes and
the effects of interest and exchange rate movements
amidst current market conditions. Looking at the
balance sheet, we see that derivatives have indeed become
a much, much bigger part of it, to the tune of £337
billion of assets, as opposed to £116 billion the year
before. Is that where it all went wrong? When you read
the reports words about derivatives, it makes them
sound as if they were used to hedge risks:
Companies in the Group transact derivatives as
principal either as a trading activity or to manage
balance sheet foreign exchange, interest rate and credit
risk. Nothing there about the famous sub-prime
mortgage derivatives which have blown up the global
banking system. When we go looking for sub-prime
elsewhere in the report, we find this: The Group has a leading position in
structuring, distributing and trading asset-backed
securities (ABS). These activities include buying
mortgage-backed securities, including securities backed
by US sub-prime mortgages, and repackaging them into
collateralised debt obligations (CDOs) for subsequent
sale to investors. The Group retains exposure to some of
the super senior tranches of these CDOs which are all
carried at fair value. At 31 December 2007 the Groups
exposure to these super senior tranches, net of hedges
and write-downs, totalled £2.6 billion to high grade
CDOs, which include commercial loan collateral as well as
prime and sub-prime mortgage collateral, and £1.3
billion to mezzanine CDOs, which are based primarily on
residential mortgage collateral. Both categories of CDO
have high attachment points.[3] There was also £1.2
billion of exposure to sub-prime mortgages through a
trading inventory of mortgage-backed securities and CDOs
and £100 million through securitisation residuals. Right. So they have a leading
position in this stuff. It consists of £2.6
billion in allegedly high grade CDOs, £1.3 billion in
the next grade down, and another £1.2 billion of diverse
exposure to sub-prime, for a total of £5.1 billion.
Granted, £5.1 billion will buy you quite a few Mars bars;
but again, how did we get from there to a £100 billion
black hole? Might the weasel word be include
meaning, theres more of this stuff but
were not discussing it here? According to the Daily Telegraph,
the answer is simple: the bank had much bigger exposure
to the sub-prime market than it admitted. During a board meeting in the summer of
2006, Sir Fred was asked by fellow directors whether the
bank had any plans to move into the sub-prime market. He
told the board that the bank would not move into sub-prime
and that, as a result, RBS is better placed than
our competitors. In the foreword to RBSs 2006
annual report, published in April 2007, Sir Fred wrote:
Sound control of risk is fundamental to the
Groups business . . . Central to this is
our long-standing aversion to sub-prime lending, wherever
we do business. On the principle that people deny
something only when theres something to deny, this
remark might be the biggest single clue anywhere in the
RBS accounts as to the risks the bank was running. RBS
turned out to have quite a lot of exposure to sub-prime
risk, and to be steadily acquiring more. On the 2007
balance sheet, it appears to be under Debt
securities. When we look at the relevant footnote,
we find that this category includes £68.302 billion of
mortgage-backed securities, up from £32.19 billion the
previous year. Aha! Already in 2006 some analysts were
citing the firm as the worlds third biggest player
in sub-prime mortgages. In her new book, Fools
Gold, Gillian Tett, the heroine who covered capital
markets for the Financial Times and who
predicted the crisis, has RBS aggressively
growing its exposure to Collateralised Debt Obligations
during this period.[4] In 2007, its
American subsidiary Greenwich Capital bought a chunk of
sub-prime mortgages from New Century Financial, one of
the biggest players in the market, which was, not
coincidentally, facing bankruptcy; RBS lent another sub-prime
player, Fremont General, $1 billion; yet another American
subsidiary of RBS, the aforementioned Citizens Bank, was
buying up US sub-prime risk, allegedly without
seeking approval from the RBS board. The Telegraph
goes on to say: It is claimed that it was not until
the summer of 2007, as Northern Rock was facing meltdown,
that Sir Fred told the board that RBS had, in fact, built
up a substantial sub-prime exposure. A spokesman
for RBS said: The reality is that, like many others,
RBS was heavily exposed to problems in sub-prime markets
via its own operations and those inherited from ABN Amro.
This is despite the fact that we did not engage directly
in sub-prime issuing. The Board was in possession of full
information and the details provided to the market in all
financial reporting reflected the Groups honestly
held opinion at the time. The experience of reading a publicly
held companys accounts is not supposed to resemble
a first encounter with late Mallarmé. But unfortunately,
it all too often does particularly in the case of
the banks. I defy anyone to study RBSs reports and
accounts and to acquire from them a full sense of the
risks the bank was taking. It is exactly as Warren
Buffett wrote in 2004: No matter how financially
sophisticated you are, you cant possibly learn from
reading the disclosure documents of a derivatives-intensive
company what risks lurk in its positions. Indeed, the
more you know about derivatives, the less you will feel
you can learn from the disclosures normally proffered you. Im not claiming that the accounts
are deliberately obfuscatory, but I am saying that there
is no way one can acquire a full understanding of what
was going on from reading them. The lack of transparency
is severe. And this was just RBS, whose arrangements
werent especially baroque by the standards of the
City and Wall Street. RBS had no involvement in the
Structured Investment Vehicles SIVs whose
main purpose is to keep things off the balance sheet.
SIVs involved borrowing short in order to lend long, the
same dazzlingly successful financial model that
underpinned Northern Rock; I use the past tense in
reference to SIVs because none of them is still in
business. They have all blown up they were hugely
involved in lending to and investing in the sub-prime
market and as a result have had to be taken onto
the balance sheet of their parent banks. SIVs were
invented by Citibank in 1988. Citibanks SIVs were
all taken back onto the balance sheet of Citigroup, the
holding company, last year, and partly as a result
Citigroup, by revenue the biggest bank in the world, lost
$32 billion dollars. On 23 November 2008 the bank
received $20 billion from the US government, with an
agreement that it would stand as guarantor for another $306
billion of the banks loans. On 27 February this
year the US government announced that it was swapping its
$25 billion in emergency aid for a 36 per cent share in
the bank. So the people who brought us the SIV have now
been the subject of two of the biggest bail-outs in
history. Now consider the Lehman Brothers balance
sheet. In their 2007 accounts, under the heading
off balance sheet arrangements, they had
derivative contracts with a face value of $738 billion.
According to them, this represented an actual value of $36.8
billion. Pocket change by comparison, but still, as it
turned out, big enough to destroy the bank. RBS, I repeat, had no involvement in
SIVs or off balance sheet investments. Its accounts are
models of clarity and translucency compared with some of
its competitors. And yet you still cant tell from
them what the hell was going on. A big part of the assets
listed on their balance sheet turned out not to be worth
anything. We have to conclude from this that with the
banks in their current condition, it isnt possible
to tell from their public accounts what the real
condition of their business is. Call that problem one.
There is another problem, however, and it is this which
compounds the difficulty with banking accounts and makes
it a critical one for the British economy. That problem
is the sheer size of the big banks. They are, by near
universal consent, too big to fail. The one time a big
bank has been allowed to go under Lehmans,
in September last year it almost destroyed the
global banking system, with consequences that are still
being felt, and will continue to be felt for a long time.
Without confident lending from banks to banks and from
banks to businesses and individuals without the
proper functioning of the credit system the global
economy comes to an abrupt screeching halt. When a bank
goes under, it destroys that confidence. So a big bank
cant be allowed to go under. Call that problem two.
Put problem one and problem two together, and we have the
current situation, in which the big banks are completely
untransparent but also too big to fail. That is a
catastrophic formula. We (the taxpaying we) have no
choice but to keep them in business, and yet no real idea
whats going on inside them. Sometimes, when you eat chilli-hot food,
the first few mouthfuls tell you nothing other than that
the food contains chilli. It takes a moment or two to
detect the presence of other flavours. Bank bail-outs and
collapses are a bit like that. At first you think
theyre all the same thats the chilli
then you notice that the spicing is in fact subtly
different. RBS might be considered a complex dish like
the Mexican mole, a chilli-and-chocolate stew with a huge
variety of textures and flavours that leaves you
uncertain what youre eating. The failure of HBOS is
more straightforward, more like a bog-standard high-street
curry. The Halifax was a former mutual society which
became Britains biggest mortgage lender. In 2001,
it merged with the Bank of Scotland to form HBOS, a new
bank to rival the Big Four on the British
high street. The company set out to dominate the mortgage
market in the UK, and did so. And thats the problem:
not fancy derivatives and sub-prime loans from the US,
not indecipherable off balance sheet SIVs, just plain old
mortgages which customers cant afford to repay.
Only 7 per cent of HBOSs troubled assets are the
fancy-pants imported sub-prime variety. The rest are all
home-grown, created during the UK housing bubble. In 2007,
HBOS had £28 million of mortgage arrears and
repossessions on its books. In 2008, that figure became
£1.13 billion. HBOS says it is making allowance for 18
per cent of its mortgage loans to go into default. These
werent for the most part the super-risky 125 per
cent loans which helped destroy Northern Rock, just
ordinary mortgages on ordinary, wildly overvalued British
homes, which have at the time of writing fallen in value
by about 20 per cent, and have an unquantified amount
still to fall. (My evidence-free personal view is that
they wont stop before theyve fallen 30 per
cent, and because markets tend to overshoot in both
directions, may well fall further.) HBOSs share
price began to drop last summer when the City became
nervous about its reliance on UK mortgages. There were
denials that the firm was in crisis, which is always a
terrible sign. In September 2008, the Big Four bank
Lloyds bought HBOS, after its boss, Victor Blank
this is the part you couldnt make up bumped
into Gordon Brown at a drinks party and got him to give
an assurance that a takeover would not be referred to the
monopolies commission. Most of us have had a few drinks at a
party and done something embarrassing, usually along the
lines of Ive-always-fancied-you-isnt-it-time-we-did-something-about-it,
but lets take comfort in the following truth: none
of us has ever done anything as embarrassing as buying
HBOS. The idea was to make Lloyds-HBOS into a giant,
dominating the British high street. The reality? Well, on
1 September 2008, a couple of weeks before the news of
the HBOS takeover, Lloyds was a much admired bank with a
strong capital base (everybody thought) trading at 303p a
share; today, 14 May, it trades at 88p a share and is
around 65 per cent owned by the British taxpayer,
following a bail-out in October 2008 (£17 billion) and
then another bail-out in March this year (cost as yet
unknown), after it became clear just how badly the HBOS
merger had affected Lloydss balance sheet. So the
failure of HBOS has dragged Lloyds down and in turn
dragged down the taxpayer, and is another thing we will
be paying for for years and perhaps decades to come. HBOS
was TBTF Too Big To Fail and Lloyds, which
was bigger, was also obviously TBTF. The combined Lloyds-HBOS
is TBTF in spades. The alert reader will have noticed that
I havent been precise about exactly how much of RBS
and Lloyds-HBOS we-the-taxpayer now own. Thats
because we dont yet know. This overlaps with the
question of what is meant by the all-encompassing word
bail-out. The term is a portmanteau one, and
it involves several different kinds of cash injection
from the government to the afflicted banks. (Afflicted
probably isnt the right word. Self-afflicted?)
The governments money has been given in return for
various different kinds of shareholding and stake,
involving distinctions between ordinary and
preference shares, exquisitely boring
distinctions which I dont propose to explore in
detail. Because RBS doesnt yet know how much of the
available capital its going to need, we dont
yet know how much of the bank we are going to end up
owning. The amount could go as high as 95 per cent. In
addition, the government has created the aforementioned
Asset Protection Scheme, as a sort of dump for the assets
that are causing all the trouble. The way it works is
that banks can put assets into the scheme, and the
government will insure them against a crash in their
value. The scheme has one of those attachment
points, in that the first chunk of the loss is
borne by the bank: in the case of RBS, the first £19.5
billion of losses is borne by the bank. Then the Asset
Protection Scheme kicks in, and the government bears 90
per cent of the rest of the losses. RBS has put £302
billion of assets into the scheme. In return for this
service, the government is charging a fee of £6.5
billion. In addition, RBS has to promise not to use tax
credits from its losses to weasel out of paying tax; it
also has to promise to keep up lending to UK homeowners
and businesses, to the tune of £25 billion over the next
12 months. The equivalent numbers for Lloyds are £260
billion in the Asset Protection Scheme, with an
attachment point of £25 billion before the scheme kicks
in. The fee is £15.6 billion, and the bank promises to
lend £14 billion over the next year to the great British
public. How much of the bank we end up owning depends on
a complicated arrangement which swaps kinds of share for
other kinds of share, and is capped at 65 per cent. Put simply, this is an insurance scheme.
The government is insuring the banks against losses on
their assets. Theres nothing unusual about such
schemes: theyre a standard feature of the banking
world. In fact, they are one of the sources of the
current crisis. In the commercial world, a deal in which
one financial institution insures another against
defaults, in return for a fee, is called a credit default
swap, or CDS. In effect, the UK government has undertaken
a CDS with our imploded banks. As chance would have it, it was CDSs
that destroyed the third of our chilli-hot financial
companies, the American insurance group AIG. That feeling
you get when youve eaten something, and a few
minutes later you think, oh-oh, I think that my dinner
just said that was a case not of adieu but au revoir?
That would be AIG. This is a gigantic insurance company,
worth $200 billion at its peak and definitively TBTF.
Entertainingly for fans of financial acronyms, AIG was
done in by CDSs on CDOs. Thats to say, it took part
in credit default swaps on collateralised debt
obligations, the pools of sub-prime mortgages whose
dramatic collapse in value last year was the proximate
cause of the financial crisis. When Lehmans
imploded last September, done in by its exposure to CDOs,
there was a panicked scramble to see who else was
carrying similar risk. When it turned out that AIG was,
and, worse, that it was valuing those assets at much
higher prices than Lehmans had, investors freaked
and the companys credit rating collapsed. That
meant that it had to post more collateral to cover its
share of risks; because credit markets had tightened up,
it couldnt borrow the money it needed; and because
it was TBTF, the US government stepped in with a bail-out
on 16 September, worth $85 billion, in return for 79.9
per cent of the company. (The bail-out Ive
said they come in different varieties was in the
form of a 24-month credit facility. To adopt an analogy
with personal finances, this meant AIG could draw on the
governments bank account.) On 8 October, AIG was
given another $37.8 billion in credit. Enough, already?
No. On 10 November the US Treasury pumped another $40
billion into the company by buying freshly issued stock
created for the purpose (this being yet another variety
of bail-out somebody should write a Bankster Bail-out
Cookbook). Finally enough, already? Dont be stupid.
On 1 March 2009 the Treasury gave the company another $30
billion and restructured the terms of its loan to make
repayments of government money less arduous. The next day
the company announced a loss for the quarter not
the year, the quarter of $62 billion, the worst
corporate results in history. Finally enough, already
already? Not necessarily. According to the US Treasury
statement accompanying the fourth bail-out: Given
the systemic risk AIG continues to pose and the fragility
of markets today, the potential cost to the economy and
the taxpayer of government inaction would be extremely
high. To stabilise AIG would take time and
possibly further government support. Thats
what Too Big To Fail means. Cost of US government
assistance to AIG thus far: $173 billion. You could put
it like this: AIG + CDS + CDO + TBTF = $173,000,000,000. We had our entertaining but essentially
distracting row over Sir Fred Knighted for Services
to Banking Goodwins pension; in the US they
had their equivalent row over bonuses paid to senior AIG
executives after the bail-outs. The bonuses totalled $165
million and it doesnt take a PR professional to see
that March 2009, after the fourth AIG bail-out,
wasnt the ideal time to have announced them.
Everyone on both sides of American politics from Obama
downwards joined in the storm of outrage, which was
followed by predictable bleating from the banksters. A
Republican senator invited the AIG executives to follow
the Japanese example and either apologise or
commit suicide. (More authentic to do both, surely?) A
Democratic senator threatened to tax the bonuses at 100
per cent. The New York Times published an AIG
executives open letter to his boss, which said he
was resigning because he hadnt been a derivatives
trader and his feelings were hurt. He seemed to be
expecting applause because he was giving away his own
bonus of $742,006.40. Good fun all round. The story was a distraction from the
real scandal about AIG, which is what was happening to
the other 99.9 per cent of the money the government was
pumping into the company. Since AIG wrote CDSs, which are
effectively insurance against losses, and since those
losses had occurred, why then the cash was going to
companies that had lost money in the credit crunch:
companies such as Société Générale, which received $11.9
billion; Goldman Sachs, $12.9 billion; Merrill Lynch, $6.8
billion; Deutsche Bank, $11.8 billion; Barclays, $8.5
billion; BNP Paribas, $4.9 billion. Nothing could better
illustrate the way in which this has become a systemic
international crisis than the fact that the US Treasury
is transferring these gigantic sums to foreign banks,
because they feel they have no choice if theyre to
keep the financial system functioning. But its a
hell of a pill for the US taxpayer to have to swallow, a
much bigger and more bitter pill than the one about the
bonuses. AIG is broke, essentially because it got its
sums wrong about the level of risk represented by CDSs.
So it cant pay its counterparties (thats the
other side of the insurance deal, the insurees). But the
counterparties made the same mistake, since they took out
insurance with an insurer who, in the event of a
structural crisis, wouldnt be able to afford to pay
them. So why are the insurees walking away whistling with
pockets full of US Treasury cash, while the US taxpayer
sits on a gigantic loss? Note that AIGs market
capitalisation the total value of all its shares
was at its lowest less than a billion dollars.
Saving the company has cost many, many times more than
buying it would have. Why therefore has the Treasury
saved it? Because AIG is Too Big To Fail. What links all these companies
and all the other companies and institutions around the
world which have been felled by the credit crunch, from
the Icelandic banks Glitnir and Landsbanki, the Belgian
bank Fortis, the Irish bank Anglo Irish, Northern Rock
which started it all, and all the other institutions that
are currently in trouble is that gigantic holes
have appeared on the left-hand side of their balance
sheets, where assets are listed. Those assets are for the
most part linked in one way or another to the collapse in
property prices in the US and elsewhere. They are often
described as toxic assets, or more
euphemistically as troubled assets, and in fact
thats how theyre named in the US scheme to
buy them from the banks, by way of rebuilding the
banks balance sheets: the Troubled Asset Relief
Programme, TARP. This is different from the British plan
to insure toxic assets, which makes the UK into a
gigantic issuer of CDSs, in favour of its troubled banks.
But the term toxic assets is misleading. It
makes me think of Superman intercepting a rocket-powered
canister of vileness unleashed by some villain and
deflecting it into space. Toxicity, however, is not some
inherent property of these assets. The assets in question
dont contain some magic property of poisonous money-juice.
Whats poisonous about them are their prices. As
Stephanie Flanders has said, it would be more accurate to
call them toxic prices it would at
least be an aid to clearer thinking. The definition is usually stated as
follows: these are assets which cant be accurately
priced, and which therefore spread uncertainty and
insecurity throughout the financial system. But that
isnt quite right. Its true that some of the
assets at the moment have no price because there is no
market for them, and its a moot point whether or
not there ever will be a market again. But many of these
assets do have prices there are buyers out there
willing to acquire them. That makes sense. Consider
Lloyds-HBOS: its obviously not true that every
mortgage sold in recent years by Halifax is a dud,
spreading poison through the companys balance sheet.
That defies common sense. Its probably the case
that the bulk of the companys mortgages, perhaps
the overwhelming bulk of them, perhaps including the
worrisome recent loans, are viable. Peoples houses
might not be worth what they paid for them, but in most
cases their owners are going to continue paying the
mortgages anyway. There must be many comparable examples
out there, of highly out-of-fashion mortgage-based
investments which arent as deeply in trouble as the
markets currently think. It might make sense, if you were
an experienced investor in those markets, to investigate
the possibility of buying some of these investments at a
bargain price. The problem is that these prices are, from
the banks point of view, too low. The buyers are
willing to acquire them at, say, 20 or 30 cents to the
dollar, so that an asset whose notional worth is $10
million a derivative tracing its value from sub-prime
mortgages, for example might have someone willing
to buy it for $2 or $3 million. For the bank, that price
is too low. It isnt too low in the sense that they
quite fancy the idea of a higher price; its too low
in the sense that, if they accept the valuation, they
have a gigantic hole on the left-hand side of the balance
sheet. Their assets arent worth what theyre
supposed to be, and the bank is no longer solvent. I guarantee that at this very moment,
somewhere in the world, somebody at one of the big banks
is sitting with his head in his hands, looking at the
companys balance sheet and sweating over this very
problem. If the global economic crisis can be reduced to
one single phenomenon, it is this: the fact that nobody
knows which banks are solvent. Because banks are crucial
to the creation and operation of credit, a bank crisis
leads directly to a credit crunch. Its also the
reason the huge amounts of money being pumped into the
banking sector by governments are tending not to do the
thing they are supposed to do, i.e. restart lending to
businesses and consumers. Thats because and
here we can have that very rare thing, a brief moment of
sympathy for the banksters the banks are being
given two totally incompatible goals. One is to rebuild
their balance sheet and recapitalise themselves so
theyre no longer at risk of going broke. The second
is to keep lending money. Theyre being told to save
and to keep spending at the same time. Its not
possible, and in the circumstances its no mystery
why banks are using every penny they can get, and calling
in every loan they can: theyre doing it in order to
deleverage and rebuild their capital as fast
as possible. What the banks want to be able to do is
what most of us would do in comparable circumstances.
Indeed, its what a good few of us, myself included,
have done in the past, during previous busts in the
property market. You just wait. Those who are in the
dreaded position of having negative equity
thats 900,000 people in the UK, with many
more due to join them in the coming months can
sell and take a loss, if they can afford to, or they can
just wait. Carry on living, and wait for prices to
recover, and even if they dont, you still have
somewhere to live. Thats what the banks would like
to do about their toxic prices: wait for them to become
non-toxic. If they were forced to value their assets
today, for the price they could get today a
practice known as mark to market, which is
supposedly enforced on most kinds of asset some of
them would be insolvent. Since the current valuations
would irretrievably trash their balance sheets, they
would prefer not to accept them. The trouble is that banks are not
households. If banks sit on their hands and wait for
valuations to recover, the economy grinds to a halt. The
flow of money would stop and the recession would be even
more severe than it is already certain to be. Thats
because a situation in which banks are insolvent but stay
in business means that you have zombie banks.
A zombie bank is a bank which is dead insolvent
but has a horrible pseudo-life because it is being
allowed to keep trading by (usually) an overindulgent
government. Zombie banks are not hypothetical: it was
zombie banks, created by a t0o-cosy relationship between
banks and the state, which after 1989 turned the Japanese
economy from a wonder of the world to a comatose onlooker
on global growth. The economy cant recover until
the zombies are killed. It isnt hard to know how to slay
the zombies. The only way to do it is to hold a gun to
the head of the various bankers those various guys
sitting with their heads in their hands staring at
balance sheets with holes in them and force them
to admit what their assets are worth, right now. Many of
the banks will turn out to be insolvent. In that case the
bank is nationalised, or at the very least goes into
administration and receivership. Then, a number of
options become available, one of the principal ones being
to break the bank up into the viable part of the business,
which will eventually be refloated back onto the market,
and a bad bank of dodgy assets which must be
sold off (or arguably held until the values recover) in
whatever way makes the most possible money for the
taxpayer. Nobody in power wants to do that.
Nobody with power in the banking system, and nobody with
power in government. Both the British and the American
plans to help the banks are very, very, very expensive
variations on the theme of sticking their fingers in
their ears and loudly singing La la la, Im
not listening. This is whats happened so far.
In Britain, on 8 October 2008, the government announced a
£500 billion rescue package. This had various components.
One was £200 billion for the Special Liquidity Scheme.
This scheme had begun in April 2008 and the new
announcement increased its size. It allows banks to swap
assets which cant be sold pretty much the
definition of a toxic asset in return for much
more sellable (in other words, liquid) nine-month
government bonds. At the time of writing, this scheme has
been taken up by banks to a value of £185 billion. The
government also created the Bank Recapitalisation Fund,
to keep the banks in business by buying their shares. An
initial £25 billion went into the scheme, with another
£25 billion available if needed. Its this money
which has been used to bail out RBS and HBOS, as above.
In addition, the government offered up to £250 billion
in loan guarantees between the banks. These were designed
to take away the uncertainty in interbank lending, the
uncertainty whose cause was the existence of toxic assets
on each others balance sheets. The government was
offering to insure these loans in other words, the
government was offering to become a one-stop shop for
credit default swaps. The distinctive feature of the UK
scheme is the way the government took stakes in the banks
as a way of recapitalising them and helping them to stay
in business. In the US it was different. There, on 1
October 2008, the Senate passed the Emergency Economic
Stabilisation Act, based on the plan floated by the then
treasury secretary, Henry Paulson. This created the
Troubled Asset Relief Programme Ive already
mentioned, a $700 billion fund designed to buy the toxic
assets from the banks. The government would then be free
to sit on them until they recovered some value, and in
the meantime could enjoy the income from the various
underlying streams of mortgage revenue since these
assets were of course mortgage-backed securities based on
the famous sub-prime mortgages. This scheme varies from
the British one in that it doesnt have the
government pumping cash into the banks to keep them
solvent, but instead has it taking the toxic assets away
deflecting them into space à la Superman
and hoping that this will in and of itself cause
normality to break out in the banking sector. There was a
not-so-subtle difficulty with the plan, however: what
price is the government to pay for the toxic assets? How
are the banks to be prevented from gouging horribly
unfair sums of money from the taxpayer? After all, the
market has broken down because the gap between what
sellers are willing to accept and buyers are willing to
pay is so great that the two parties cant do deals.
So the government waltzes in and agrees to be the patsy,
overpaying for assets which the bank knows far more about
than the government does? Its not just buying a pig
in a poke: its buying a pig in a poke at a price
determined by the seller, at a time when there is no
market in pigs. That problem proved unfixable. The
banks and the government couldnt agree prices for
the assets to go into TARP. Instead, the government found
itself putting money directly into the banks in return
for shareholdings, in a less structured version of the
British approach. So far $250 billion has gone into the
banks in this way; its this money which has
underpinned the bail-outs to date, plus the extra $40
billion into AIG. The current cost to the US taxpayer of
TARP so far is estimated at $356 billion. That got
through about half the $700 billion Congress had
allocated to the bail-out. In February, the new treasury
secretary, Tim Geithner, announced the outline of his
plan for the rest of the money, and then on 23 March the
detail of the plan came out. It has three different
components, all of which involve the creation of public-private
partnerships between the government and private investors.
One part of the plan matches private money with
government money, while also offering to lend up to 85
per cent of the private stake. (We decide to buy
something for £100. I lend you £92.50, £85 of it on
loan, and you pay £7.50.) Another part has the
government putting up a chunk of money to buy toxic
assets, and offers a line of credit to buy more assets,
provided that private money goes in too. This part of the
plan is called the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan
Facility or TALF (presumably TABSLF was viewed as
unpronounceable but I cant be the only
person to find in TALF a faint, embarrassing shadow of
the porny acronym MILF). This additional government money
comes in the form of a non-recourse loan
thats to say, the government cant ask
for its money back, if the investment goes wrong. The non-recourse
loans can constitute up to 85 per cent of the total
investment. The private investors get all the upside if
the price goes up. This is a truly amazing sweetener to
persuade private money in practice, if the plan
works, that will be made up of hedge funds, sovereign
wealth funds and private equity groups to get
involved in buying up the toxic assets. The idea, the
hope, the longing, is that this will create a market in
the assets; and once a functioning market is created, the
thinking goes, the market will realise that these assets
are in fact undervalued, and the prices will recover, and
bank balance sheets will recover, and peace and order
will break out and the financial sector will be restored
to health. Itll be like the last act of Fidelio,
except the people emerging from the cellars blinking with
joy will be bankers. To the relevant bigshots of the
financial sector people Tim Geithner knows well
from his time as head of the New York Federal Reserve
this plan represents a bold, sane, ingenious
attempt to create a space for the so-called assets to
return to their rightful values. To many other observers,
its not so different from dressing up in a costume
and dancing in a circle praying for the intervention of
the Market Gods. The plan embodies a desperate yearning
for this to be a crisis of liquidity rather than one of
solvency, and hopes that by acting on that belief, it
will make it come true. About twenty years ago I bumped into
Alan Hollinghurst at a party at the Poetry Society. He
greeted me with the words, Hello. Im going to
tremendous, Basil Fawltyish lengths to avoid being
introduced to Sir Stephen Spender, whose collected
poems he had just given an unglowing review.
Tremendous, Basil Fawltyish lengths: that
phrase stuck with me. It comes to mind when I look at
Anglo-Saxon attempts to address the crises in their
respective financial sectors. The UK and US plans are
different, as Ive said, but at their heart they
both show the governments going to tremendous, Basil
Fawltyish lengths in order to avoid taking the troubled
banks into public ownership. Our governments are prepared
to pay for them, but not to take them over. There are four reasons for the
reluctance to take over the banks, of which the first
isnt a real reason but a piece of political
bullshit. 1. Because the government would be bad
at it. This is the only reason governments are willing to
give in public, and it fails the most elementary test of
all: only a professional politician can say it with a
straight face. Bad at running the banks, compared to the
bankers who broke capitalism? Please. But this is the
closest they can get to admitting the first real reason,
which is: 2. Because if the banks were taken over,
then every decision they take would come at a potential
political cost to the government. Your state-owned
mortgage lender is threatening to repossess your house,
after you fell behind on the payments? Blame the
government. Your firm is laying off half its workforce
because the bank wont roll over its loan? Blame the
government. This, of course, is in addition to all the
other economic things for which people are already
blaming the government. People are grumbling now, but to
nothing like the extent they would if the banks were
directly owned by the state. Politicians simply
arent willing to take on the responsibility for the
banks actions. 3. They also dont want to admit
the extent to which we are all now liable for the losses
made by the banks. Guess what, though: its too late.
The 30 per cent collapse in the value of sterling over
the last months is something which is only just beginning
to be noticed by the public at large; but it is unlikely
to go away as quickly as it arrived. The reason sterling
has crashed is simple: the markets are pricing in the
fact that we the taxpayer are on the hook for the losses
made by our banks. The markets assume that we cant
or wont default on our government debts that
would mean we simply cant afford to pay back the
amount were currently borrowing. Theyre
probably right about that. But Alistair Darlings
desperately grim Budget made it clear just how deep in
the mire we are. As for how bad it is, and how quickly
its gone bad, well: in March last year, at the time
of the Budget, the projected deficit for 2009-10 was £38
billion. By 24 November, the projected deficit was £118
billion. In the Budget on 22 April, Darling admitted that
the real figure is going to be £175 billion. The total
projected borrowing for the next four years is £606
billion. National debt will hit 79 per cent of GDP
the highest peacetime figure ever. The economy is going
to have its worst year since 1945. The debt is going to
cost in the range of £35 to £47 billion a year to
service. Thats just the debt alone; were
going to be spending more on debt than we are on the
entire transport budget. Perhaps New Labour might
consider changing its motto from Education,
education, education to Debt, debt,
debt. That means tax rises, a near total
freeze on government spending, swingeing public-sector
job cuts, companies laying off every worker they can to
save costs, and a dramatic upward spike in unemployment.
The one easy thing the government will be able to do to
help itself is to make inflation go up that helps,
because it decreases the real cost of the debt. An
inflation rate of 5 per cent means that the debt goes
down in cost by 5 per cent every year, magically and just
by itself. From the point of view of a heavily indebted
government, thats good news; for other parts of the
economy, for borrowers and for anyone holding sterling,
its less good. To compound this already desperate
picture, we also have huge levels of personal debt,
directly arising from our credit bubble. The average
British household owes 160 per cent of its annual income.
That makes us, individually and collectively, a lot like
the cartoon character whos run off the end of a
cliff and hasnt realised it yet. None of this is
secret, and investors looking at the prospects for
sterling are making up their minds and bailing out. The
investor-pundit Jim Rogers, colleague of George Soros, is
advising anyone who will listen to sell any
sterling you might have. Its finished. I hate to
say it, but I would not put any money in the UK.
This isnt nice or polite, but it puts into the
public domain what a lot of international money men are
saying in private. More to the point, its a policy
on which they have already acted. This is the reason an
auction of government debt held in March failed. The debt
was for 40-year bonds paying out at a rate of 4.25 per
cent, and the reason it failed to sell everything on
offer the last time that happened was in 2002
is that the markets thought inflation likely to
rise, making the bonds a bad bet. And the reason for that is that we in
Britain are, to use a technical economic term, screwed.
Economies across the whole world are struggling. Because
nobody is spending money, even relatively blameless
countries such as Germany, with low levels of debt and
workforces who actually make things, are having a
difficult time. Germanys economy is predicted to
contract by 5.4 per cent this year. A banker explained it
like this: When your countrys economy depends
on people buying a car every three years, and they decide
that theyll only buy a car every five years,
youre fucked. Off a cliff. So the German
economy is fucked off a cliff. But it will recover, when
people start buying cars again, and when it does, at
least their underlying levels of debt are manageable.
Something similar goes for Spain, where the ending of the
property boom has caused a spike in unemployment to 17.4
per cent, almost doubling in a year, or Ireland, which
has contracted by a truly horrendous 8 per cent and where
people have gone from owning private helicopters to
losing their homes in six months flat. All of these
countries are in deep trouble. But there are four things
you dont want to have, going into the current
crisis. 1. You dont want to have had a boom based
on a property bubble. 2. You dont want to have a
consumer credit bubble. 3. You dont want to have an
economy based on financial services. 4. You dont
want your government to have just gone on a massive
spending spree. We have all four of those things that you
dont want. It is possible that we are on course
for the worst-case scenario. That would involve all our
big, TBTF banks turning out to be insolvent, with the
result that their balance sheets go onto the public debt.
If that were to happen, Britain itself could become
insolvent. Countries do go broke. A famous-to-economists
example was Newfoundland, which in 1934 effectively went
into administration and opted for direct rule from
Britain because it was broke becoming in the
process one of the only colonies anywhere in the world
ever to have voluntarily given up independence. A modern-day
equivalent is having to go to the IMF and ask for money.
It happened in 1976 and could happen again. The trigger
would be a general view in the markets that the
governments tax receipts werent sufficient to
meet its debt payments. That would cause a
buyers strike in the bond market:
nobody would want to buy UK government bonds, so the
government could no longer keep going back to the markets
for cash to pay its liabilities. That would leave the
government facing an immediate need for cash with no
means of raising it and its that which would
send us prostrate to the IMF. Sterling would be more or
less worthless. Travel would be next to impossible,
imports would be unaffordable, interest rates would zoom
up and stay up, there would be cuts in all aspects of
public sector spending, especially employment. It would
be brutal. Nobody thinks this scenario is likely, but
quite a few people are willing to admit that it is
possible. In 1976, Britain went broke running an annual
deficit the gap between tax revenues and
government spending of 6 per cent of GDP. Next
year that figure is going to hit 12.4 per cent. A bad
omen. Even if we fall short of the IMF option
in favour of a run-of-the-mill severe recession, the
consequences for Britain are going to be horrific. Roads
and schools and hospitals will go unbuilt and unrepaired,
medical treatments will go unbought, nurses and policemen
and council workers will be laid off. Six hundred
thousand jobs have been created in local government in
the last few years. Most of them will have to go. And
then the really gigantic argument will have to be had,
over the public service pensions which are paid for out
of current tax receipts. I dont know anyone who has
studied this problem who thinks the government will be
able to afford them. Can you imagine the fights that are
going to happen? The political polarisation between
public and private sector employees, the savagery of the
cuts, the bitterness of the arguments, the furious sense
of righteousness on both sides? Itll be Thatcher
all over again, and the current period of managerial non-politics
will seem as distant as the Butskellite consensus did in
the 1980s. All of this leads us to the fourth and
deepest reason why the government wont nationalise
the banks. The deepest reason is: 4. Because it would be so embarrassing.
Some of the embarrassment is superficial: on the not-remembering-somebodys-name-at-a-social-occasion
level. The Anglo-Saxon economies have had decades of boom
mixed with what now seem, in retrospect, smallish periods
of downturn. During that they/we have shamelessly
lectured the rest of the world on how they should be
running their economies. Weve gloated at the French
fear of debt, laughed at the Germans 19th-century
emphasis on manufacturing, told the Japanese that they
cant expect to get over their lost
decade until they kill their zombie banks, and so
on. Its embarrassing to be in a worse condition
than all of them. There is, however, a deeper
embarrassment, one which verges on a form of
psychological or ideological crisis. To nationalise major
financial institutions would mean that the Anglo-Saxon
model of capitalism had failed. The level of state
intervention in the US and UK at this moment is
comparable to that of wartime. We have in effect had to
declare war to get us out of the hole created by our
economic system. There is no model or precedent for this,
and no way to argue that its all right really,
because under such-and-such a model of capitalism . . .
there is no such model. It just isnt supposed to
work like this, and there is no road-map for whats
happened. Its for this reason that the
thing the governments least want to do take over
the banks is something that needs to happen, not
just for economic reasons, but for ethical ones too.
There needs to be a general acceptance that the current
model has failed. The brakes-off, deregulate or die,
privatise or stagnate, lunch is for wimps, greed is good,
whats good for the financial sector is good for the
economy model; the sack the bottom 10 per cent, bonus-driven,
if you cant measure it, it isnt real model;
the model that spread from the City to government and
from there through the whole culture, in which the idea
of value has gradually faded to be replaced by the idea
of price. Thatcher began, and Labour continued, the
switch towards an economy which was reliant on financial
services at the expense of other areas of society. What
was equally damaging for Britain was the hegemony of
economic, or quasi-economic, thinking. The economic
metaphor came to be applied to every aspect of modern
life, especially the areas where it simply didnt
belong. In fields such as education, equality of
opportunity, health, employees rights, the social
contract and culture, the first conversation to happen
should be about values; then you have the conversation
about costs. In Britain in the last 20 to 30 years that
has all been the wrong way round. There was a reverse
takeover, in which City values came to dominate the whole
of British life. Its becoming traditional at this
point to argue that perhaps the financial crisis will be
good for us, because it will cause people to rediscover
other sources of value. I suspect this is wishful
thinking, or thinking about something which is quite a
long way away, because it doesnt consider just how
angry people are going to get when they realise the
extent of the costs we are going to carry for the next
few decades. I think we will end up nationalising at
least some of our big banks because the electorate will
be too angry to do anything that looks in the smallest
degree like letting them get away with it. Banks
cant change their behaviour, so we have to do it
for them, and the only way to do it is to take them over.
We cant afford any more TBTF. I get the strong impression, talking to
people, that the penny hasnt fully dropped. As the
ultra-bleak condition of our finances becomes more and
more apparent people are going to ask increasingly angry
questions about how we got into this predicament. The
drop in sterling, for instance, means that prices for all
sorts of goods will go up just as oil and gas prices have
spiked downwards. Combined with job losses a
million people are forecast to lose their jobs this year,
taking unemployment back to Thatcherite levels and
tax rises, and inflation, and the increasing realisation
that the cost of the financial crisis is going to be paid
not over a few years but over a generation, we have a
perfect formula for a deep and growing anger.
Expectations have risen a lot, over the last three
decades; thats going to have a big impact on how
furious people feel about the hard years ahead. The level
of future public spending cuts implied in Darlings
recent budget which included the laughably
optimistic idea that the economy will grow by 1.25 per
cent next year is greater than the level of cuts
implemented by Thatcher. Remember, thats the
optimistic version. If were lucky, it wont be
any worse than Thatcherism. [1] Neal Ascherson wrote about the
Darien Scheme in the LRB of 3 January 2008. [2] They go to some lengths to make
sure its that way, since Apple is, in financial
circles, notorious for sitting on huge amounts of cash.
In the balance sheet were looking at, Apple had $24.49
billion in cash. Thats a colossal amount, as much
as RBS, a company fifty times its size. This cash,
obviously, stays on the asset side of the balance sheet.
You might think that having lots of cash is a good thing,
but in investment circles it isnt loved: the logic
is that if you have cash, you should give that cash back
to its ultimate owners, the shareholders. They might have
other things they want to do with it. [3] My footnote, not RBSs: an
attachment point is the same thing as the
excess in an insurance policy. It means the point at
which the insurer shells out. I quite like it as a
corporate euphemism, embodying as it does an image of the
insured person desperately trying to attach himself to
the insurer, while implying that the insurer is keen for
this not to happen. Translated, high attachment
points means these crappy mortgage-borrowers
need to have lost a lot of money before they become our
problem. [4] Fools Gold will be
reviewed in the LRB by Donald MacKenzie.
|