![]() |
||
THE HANDSTAND | september 2004 |
|
Bank with close ties to Bush administration engulfed in scandal By Joseph Kay 24 August 2004 The Justice Department announced on Friday that it is launching a criminal investigation into Riggs Bank. In recent months, the Washington-based bank has become engulfed in a scandal related to charges of money-laundering, corruption and terrorist financing. Riggs, which touts itself as the most important bank in the most important city in the world, has been known for decades as the bank of the Washington elite, including politicians, foreign ambassadors and the wealthy. It has held presidential accounts stretching back to the time of the Civil War, and is a prominent fixture in the political and social establishment of the nations capital. Or rather, it was a prominent fixture. In July, PNL Financial Services agreed to buy Riggs for $779 million. The sale will become final by early next year. The banks prominent embassy and international operations will be shut down in an attempt to bury a scandal that has the potential of becoming much larger. That an institution like Riggs could so quickly disintegrate is an indication of the extent of the corruption that has overtaken American finance and government. There are three separate activities for which Riggs has come under investigation: (1) its relationship with the Saudi royal family and the potential financing of two of the September 11 hijackers through an account owned by the wife of the Saudi ambassador; (2) its relationship with the corrupt and dictatorial regime of the oil-rich West African country of Equatorial Guinea; and (3) its banking business with the former military dictator of Chile, Augusto Pinochet. The Saudi accounts The public revelations concerning the banks relationship with Saudi Arabia came mainly through the publication of a Newsweek article on December 2, 2002 (The Saudi Money Trail). The news magazine reported that in January 2000, two of the hijackers who were on the plane that crashed into the PentagonNawaf Alhazmi and Khalid Almihdharreceived monetary aid and other assistance from Omar al-Bayoumi. Alhazmi and Almihdhar are at the center of suspicions of US government complicity in the 9/11 attacksand for good reason. The CIA had identified the two as early as January 2000 as Al Qaeda operatives, and the Washington Post reported in June 2002 that the FBI also knew of the two from January of 2000. Yet they were allowed to enter the US and live openly in San Diego for 18 months prior to the terrorist attacks on New York and Washington. Newsweek reported in September 2002 that the roommate of Alhazmi and Almihdhar in San Diego was an FBI informant! According to the December 2002 Newsweek article on Riggs Bank, al-Bayoumi apparently did work for Dallah Avco, an aviation-services company with extensive contracts with the Saudi Ministry of Defense and Aviation, headed by Prince Sultan, the father of the Saudi ambassador to the United States, Prince Bandar. According to informed sources, some federal investigators suspect that al-Bayoumi could have been an advance man for the 9/11 hijackers, sent by Al Qaeda to assist the plot that ultimately claimed 3,000 lives. Al-Bayoumi may have been receiving assistance in his activities from sections of the Saudi royal family. The Newsweek article states: About two months after al-Bayoumi began aiding Alhazmi and Almihdhar, Newsweek has learned, al-Bayoumis wife began receiving regular stipends, often monthly and usually around $2,000 and totaling tens of thousands of dollars. The money came in the form of cashiers checks, purchased from Washingtons Riggs Bank by Princess Haifa bin Faisal, the daughter of the late King Faisal and wife of Prince Bandar, the Saudi envoy who is a prominent Washington figure and personal friend of the Bush family. The checks were sent to a woman named Majeda Ibrahin Dweikat, who in turn signed over many of them to al-Bayoumis wife... Dweikats husband, Osama Basnan, is reported to be a sympathizer of Al Qaeda and is known to have had friendly relations with the two hijackers, Alhazmi and Almihdhar. Al-Bayoumi apparently came under suspicion shortly after the attacks of September 11. He was picked up by British intelligence, which found evidence that he had made two phone calls to diplomats at the Saudi Embassy in Washington. However, he was released and is reported to be in Saudi Arabia. Further, according to Newsweek: Osama Basnan showed up in Houston last April [2001] while Saudi Crown Prince Abdullah came to town with a vast entourage en route to President George W. Bushs ranch. According to informed sources, Basnan met with a high Saudi prince who has responsibilities for intelligence matters and is known to bring suitcases full of cash into the United States. There are suspicions that Basnan may have been a member of Saudi intelligence, suggesting that Saudi intelligence was closely monitoring, if not aiding, the activity of the September 11 hijackers through its accounts at Riggs. Newsweek noted that the FBI, as of December 2002, still had an investigation open into the transactions. In July 2003, the FBI accused Riggs Bank of failing to abide by anti-money-laundering (AML) regulations. Prior to and after the attacks of September 11, it was not unusual for Saudi clients to transfers of millions of dollars in and out of the bank with no questions asked. This was in violation of AML regulations, which require the reporting of all transaction involving such large sums of money. The bank was eventually fined $25 million in May 2004 for violating these regulations. However, the FBI has issued a statement saying it found no evidence of terrorist financing. The Bush administration has refused to release the intelligence behind the investigation, citing national security concerns. Even after the FBIs accusations in July 2003, the bank continued to allow massive cash transfers by the Saudi ambassador. Under pressure, the bank announced this past March that it was closing all Saudi accounts. Equatorial Guinea and General Pinochet On July 14, 2004, the Minority Staff of the US Senate Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, at the request of Democrat Carl Levin, the ranking minority member of the subcommittee, issued a report that dealt mainly with the banks accounts for Equatorial Guinea and Augusto Pinochet. The report found that the evidence reviewed by the Subcommittee staff establishes that, since at least 1997, Riggs has disregarded its anti-money laundering (AML) obligations, maintained a dysfunctional AML program despite frequent warnings from OCC [Office of the Comptroller of the Currency] regulators, and allowed or, at times, actively facilitated suspicious financial activity. The OCC, a branch of the Treasury Department, is responsible for regulating nationally chartered banks. Equatorial Guinea was Riggs largest client. It held over 60 accounts at the bank, with varied holdings of $300-700 million. Its ruler, Teodoro Obian Nguema Mbasogo, came to power in a military coup in 1979 and is infamous for his corruption and brutality. Relations with the United States became strained in the mid-1990s, when the Clinton administration broke off diplomatic ties. However, these were restored by the Bush administration in 2003. The country holds interest for the United States because of its large oil reserves. Riggs appears to have held both Equatorial Guinea government treasury accounts and the personal accounts of Obiang, his family members, and ministers in his government. According to the subcommittee report, Riggs serviced the EG [Equatorial Guinean] accounts with little or no attention to the banks anti-money laundering obligations... For example, Riggs opened multiple personal accounts for the President of Equatorial Guinea, his wife, and other relatives; helped establish shell offshore corporations for the EG President and his sons; and over a three-year period, from 2000 to 2002, facilitated nearly $13 million in cash deposits into Riggs accounts controlled by the EG President and his wife. Riggs also opened an account that received large sums of money from oil companies that did business with Equatorial Guinea, including Exxon Mobil, Amerada Hess, Marathon Oil and ChevronTexaco. Riggs allowed the wire transfer of over $35 million from the account to two unknown companies. The Subcommittee has reason to believe that at least one of these recipient companies is controlled in whole or in part by the EG President. Riggs appears to have acted as a conduit for large-scale bribes or other corrupt machinations between the giant oil corporations and the dictator of a country with which they were eager to do business. The report also noted that these oil companies made a number of large payments (sometimes valued at over $1 million) to individual officials or family members for a variety of services. The manager of Riggs accounts for Equatorial Guinea was Simon P. Kareri, who was eventually fired by the bank in January 2004. According to a bank employee, on more than one occasion Kareri visited the Equatorial Guinean embassy and returned with a suitcase full of $3 million in cash, which was deposited in the bank with no reports to financial regulators. According to the subcommittee report, The bank leadership permitted [Kareri] ...to become closely involved with EG officials and business activities, including advising the EG government on financial matters and becoming the sole signatory on an EG account holding substantial funds. The bank exercised such lax oversight of the account managers activities that, among other misconduct, the account manager was able to wire transfer more than $1 million from the EG oil account at Riggs to another bank for an account opened in the name of Jadini Holdings, an offshore corporation controlled by the account managers wife. In addition to its dealings with the Saudi royal family and Equatorial Guineas dictator, Riggs had a close relationship with the former dictator of Chile, Augusto Pinochet. Pinochet held numerous active accounts at Riggs between 1994 and 2002, even while he was under house arrest in Britain and his assets were supposedly frozen. According to the subcommittee report, The aggregate deposits in the Pinochet accounts at Riggs ranged from $4 to $8 million at a time.... Riggs account managers took actions consistent with helping Mr. Pinochet to evade legal proceedings seeking to discover and attach his bank accounts.... Riggs opened multiple accounts and accepted millions of dollars in deposits from Mr. Pinochet with no serious inquiry into questions regarding the source of his wealth; helped him set up offshore shell corporations and open accounts in the names of those corporations to disguise his control of the accounts; altered the names of his personal accounts to disguise their ownership; transferred $1.6 million from London to the United States while Mr. Pinochet was in detention and the subject of a court order to attach his bank accounts; conducted transactions through Riggs own accounts to hide Mr. Pinochets involvement in some cash transactions; and delivered over $1.9 million in cashiers checks to Mr. Pinochet in Chile to enable him to obtain substantial cash payments from banks in that country. The scope of the corruption, money-laundering and other suspicious activities is indeed astonishing. While it was engaged in these activities, the bank operated under the not-so-watchful eye of the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. In spite of clear indications of regulatory violations at least as early as 1997, the OCC took no actions. Particularly closely involved with the OCCs investigation into the Pinochet accounts was the comptrollers examiner-in-charge, R. Ashley Lee, who worked at the OCC from 1998 to October 2002. According to the subcommittee report, In 2001, [Lee]...advised more senior OCC personnel against taking a formal enforcement action against Riggs, because the bank had promised to correct identified AML deficiencies. In 2002, he ordered examiners not to include a memorandum or work papers on the Pinochet examination to the OCCs electronic database. Lee went to work for Riggs two weeks later, quickly becoming an executive vice president and the chief risk officer. The subcommittee report states: During his next 18-months at the bank, he attended a number of meetings with OCC personnel related to Riggs AML problems, despite regulations prohibiting former OCC employees from attending meetings on OCC-related maters. Ties to the Bush family The revelations of the activities at Riggs Bank demonstrate how commonplace and extensive criminal activity has become within the American financial and political establishment. Not coincidentally, the banks activity has a great deal in common with certain features prominent in the Bush administration: the heavy influence of oil interests, the close ties with the Saudi ruling elite, the funding and support given to dictators and former dictators, including General Pinochet. The relationship of Riggs to the Bush administration is more than tangential. Riggs owns a money management firm, J. Bush & Co., operated by Jonathan Bush, the brother of George H.W. Bush and the current presidents uncle. Jonathan Bush played a very important role in helping find investors for the various failed oil businesses that George W. Bush ran before he began his career in politics. Jonathan Bush also helped raise money for George H.W. Bush and is a former chair of the New York Republican State Finance Committee. In 2000, he was briefly named president and CEO of Riggs Investment Management Company (RIMCO), a wholly owned subsidiary of Riggs Bank. While Jonathan Bush appears not to have been directly involved in the Saudi, Pinochet or Equatorial Guinean accounts, his position at Riggs is an indication of the close ties between the bank and the Bush family. Moreover, Riggs is owned by the Allbritton family, a Texas family with close ties to the Republican establishment. Joe Allbritton, the former head of Riggs who bought the bank in the mid-1970s, is a friend of the Bush family. His son, Robert Allbritton, is the current chairman and CEO. The Allbritton family is known among the Washington elite for the party it traditionally holds after the annual Alfalfa Club dinner, hosted to mark the birthday of Robert E. Lee, the southern general in the Civil War. The New York Times (A Washington Bank, A Global Mess, April 11, 2004) notes, The Alfalfa roster includes presidents, politicians, diplomats and business impresarios, all bound together by being either formidably influential or fabulously rich. Attendees have included luminaries like Prince Bandar bin Sultan, Saudi Arabias ambassador to the United States; Jack Valenti, the president of the Motion Picture Association of America; and others with surnames like Greenspan, Kissinger and Rehnquist. President Bush and Vice President Dick Cheney made their first joint public appearance after the Sept. 11 terrorist attacks at the Alfalfa gathering in 2002. Valenti, who, like Allbritton and Bush, is a former Texas businessman, is also on the board of directors of Riggs Bank. A television station also owned by Allbritton was in the news earlier this year after it refused to air an ad critical of the Bush administrations policy in Iraq. Perhaps even more than the Enron scandal, the Riggs scandal is a deeply political scandal. No doubt, much of what went on at Riggs remains to be uncovered. With the announced sale of Riggs to PNL, which will be completed by early next year, the owners of the bank are clearly attempting to contain the scandals fallout. Forwarded by Robert Nohejl ,The News Report. Fiat's
Reprieve: Saving the by Bob Landis
Agent K: Did he say anything to you? Officer Edwards: Yeah, he said the world was coming to an end. Agent K: Did he say when?Men in Black (2001) Reading the pro-gold
submissions incorporated in the Report of
the U.S. Gold Commission
twenty-some years ago is a humbling exercise. A lot of
those old commentaries could have been written today.
They say just what gold bugs say now: our monetary system
is doomed, and its end will be marked by a major monetary
crisis. The concluding chapter of the Minority Report
(Volume II, Annex A) put it thus:[1] Ahem. To state the obvious, the gold
bugs of a generation ago got it wrong. Congress did not
adopt their sound money recommendations, and yet the sky
did not fall, the paper-based system muddled through
famously, and in fact it was gold that entered into a 20
year bear market in dollar terms.
Left unaddressed, this bad call makes it easy to dismiss the balance of the Minority Report as similarly flawed or at best irrelevant. Moreover, it implicitly impeaches the credibility of all sound money advocates even today. After all, why should anyone pay attention to a bunch of Chicken Littles whove been demonstrably wrong for a generation? So it behooves us to address this question, and examine why we didnt slip into terminal monetary crisis, as predicted, back in the 1980s. Our inquiry will take us through
jargon-infested waters, so we will take pains to define
our terms. We write as gold bugs, but we will also be
guided by the teachings of the great Austrian economists,
principally Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. To understand how our monetary system was rescued, we first need to get clear on what that system is.[3] This is not as easy as it should be. Thats because in substance its just a government printing press, of the type reflected in the foregoing quote from Mises. But in form its a holdover from an earlier time when we had a fractional reserve banking system with gold as the reserve asset. The structure and terminology of our current system only make sense in their original context, where, for all the many problems associated with fractional reserve banking, there was at least something real at the heart of it. Given the disconnect between form and substance in our current system, the enormous confusion that now attends the subject, even on the part of knowledgeable people, is perfectly understandable. But it makes a brief review of Fed 101 essential to making sense of what happened in the 1980s. The creation of our fiat money, that is, money issued by decree, or fiat, occurs in two phases. Phase I is controlled by the Fed, which does two things. First, it sets the level of non interest-bearing reserves that banks are required to hold, expressed as a percentage of their checking deposit base. That percentage is known as the reserve ratio. Adjusting this ratio up or down has a massive contractionary or expansionary impact on the money supply, given the multiplier effect described below, and for that reason it has been left alone for years at a marginal rate of 10%. Banks must maintain these reserves either in the form of Federal Reserve Notes kept on hand (vault cash), or in the form of balances held in an account at a Federal Reserve Bank (reserve balances). Second, the Fed creates the reserves, and injects them into the banking system. This is where the gulf between form and substance is most telling, causing reasonable people to marvel at the brazenness of it all. The Fed creates reserves out of thin air, in the form of fresh paper notes (Federal Reserve Notes or dollars) that it prints up, or in the form of checks written on itself. It can inject reserves into the banking system in two ways. One way is to lend them to specific banks, at a rate of interest known as the discount rate. Reserves borrowed in this fashion are called, logically enough, borrowed reserves. This used to be an important tool of monetary policy, but is rarely used today. The other way is to buy things, and pay for them with cash or credit. This is the primary tool today. Whatever the Fed buys, or monetizes, goes on its balance sheet as an asset. Whatever it spends, goes on the Feds balance sheet as a liability, but becomes a reserve asset on the books of the vendor, or on the books of the vendors bank, if the vendor itself is not a bank. These transactions occur either through outright purchases and sales, which have a relatively long-term impact on the level of reserves in the system, or, more commonly, through temporary arrangements known as repurchase agreements, most of which unwind quickly. The Fed buys things only from a select group of friendly finance contractors, now 22 in number, known collectively as primary dealers.[4] Some of these primary dealers are banks themselves; the rest operate through other member banks. Reserves created by means of these purchase and sale transactions are known as non-borrowed reserves. Once the Fed has bought something and paid for it with reserves thus created out of thin air, Phase II kicks in. Phase II is controlled by the banks and the banks customers in what remains in form, despite the ethereal quality of it all, a fractional reserve banking system. The new reserve asset, which the vendor bank received in payment from the Fed, gives the bank the power to begin a process of creating more new money. The aggregate amount of new money that can be created is a multiple of the new reserve asset, equal to the reciprocal of the marginal reserve ratio, today, 10. To illustrate this process, Rothbard walks us through it, step by step.[5] Say the Fed buys an asset for $10 from Big Bank One. That $10 will support another $100 of fresh money in the banking system in the form of new customer deposit accounts. But the new $100 doesnt materialize all at once, or on the books of Big Bank One alone. Instead, it comes into being as the result of a gradual series of loan transactions that Big Bank One sets in motion. In what Rothbard calls a ripple effect, Big Bank One lends out a portion of the $10, namely $9, (1 minus the reserve requirement, or .9, times $10). That $9 ultimately gets deposited at Big Bank Two, which is the second stop in the series. Big Bank Two lends out .9 times the $9, or $8.10, and so forth, throughout the series. At the end of the series, the total new money thus created in the form of fresh deposit accounts is roughly equal to $100. Thus is our money borrowed into existence. The same process works in reverse if the Fed, instead of buying something, sells it. This has the effect of draining reserves from the banking system, and will result in a similarly high powered contraction of the money supply. The Fed buys things from, and sells things to, its primary dealers in what are known as open market transactions, so called because the Fed is operating outside its cloistered walls in the open market. The contact point is a trading desk set up in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, one of the 12 regional Fed branches. The Desk is daily in the market for U.S. Treasury securities, which comprises one of the deepest and most liquid markets in the world, with average daily turnover in the hundreds of billions of dollars. It does so in order to implement the monetary policy adopted by the Fed Open Market Committee (the FOMC) in its monthly meetings, now followed breathlessly, often without the slightest comprehension, by a host of commentators. The way Open Market Operations work is at root quite simple. The Desk and the primary dealers maintain a market in reserves, the so called Fed funds market. To increase the supply of reserves in the banking system, the Desk will buy Treasuries from the primary dealers, on either a short or a longer term basis, thereby putting fresh cash in their pockets. If the supply of fresh reserves on offer from the Fed exceeds the systems demand, as reflected in the primary dealers appetite, the price of those reserves, the so-called Fed funds rate, will tend to go down. Conversely, to decrease reserves in the banking system, the Desk will in effect bid for reserves by offering securities from its portfolio. This requires the buying primary dealers to cough up cash, thereby draining reserves. If the Feds demand for reserves from the primary dealers exceeds the supply available, the price of reserves, the Fed funds rate, will tend to go up. Note that these simple hydraulics give the Fed only two things it can focus on in implementing monetary policy. It can focus on the quantity of reserves in the system. Or, it can focus on the price of those reserves, the Fed funds rate. Thats it. If it focuses on quantity, it will pick a level of reserves its happy with and stick with it, regardless of ebb and flow of demand from within the system. If it focuses on price, it will be darting in and out of the market with countless transactions at the margin designed to keep the Fed funds rate, rather than the quantity of reserves in the system, at a desired level. As to the quantity of money out in the system, the Fed has direct control over just one thing: the monetary base, or base money. This is the sum of Federal Reserve Notes outstanding and reserve balances, that is, member bank reserve-deposits at Fed banks. The power to create base money is limited. It does not extend to the many other permutations of paper that make up the alphabet soup of the so-called monetary aggregates, the Ms we hear so much about:[6] M1, which consists of currency, travelers checks, demand deposits and other checkable deposits; M2, which consists of M1 plus savings deposits (including money market deposit accounts) and small denomination (under $100,000) time deposits issued by financial institutions; and shares in retail money market mutual funds (funds with initial investments under $50,000), net of retirement accounts; M3, which consists of M2 plus
large-denomination ($100,000 or more) time deposits;
repurchase agreements issued by depository institutions;
Eurodollar deposits, specifically, dollar-denominated
deposits due to nonbank U.S. addresses held at foreign
offices of U.S. banks worldwide and all banking offices
in Canada and the United Kingdom; and institutional money
market mutual funds (funds with initial investments of
$50,000 or more); and the most recent (and arguably the
trendiest) entry, The Feds control over the monetary aggregates declines as the subscript numbers get bigger. M3, for example, includes institutional money market funds with a $50,000 minimum investment. This element of broad money is totally outside the Feds purview. No reserves need be posted against any money market funds, let alone those held by big institutions. Technically, such funds should not be considered fiat money at all, as they are not immediately convertible into cash. Nevertheless, they are a prominent component in a monetary aggregate that is closely identified with Fed policy. Even M1, the narrowest monetary aggregate, consists principally of things not subject to the Feds direct control. So when you read breathless Internet commentary that claims the Fed is ramping up, or chopping, M3, you know you are in the presence of a misunderstanding. As to the price of money
in the system, we see that the Fed can directly influence
the Fed funds rate through its open market operations.
But this is just overnight money. How does the Fed funds
rate actually influence the price of money farther out on
the yield curve? According to the Feds website, it
just does: it triggers events: Right. Actually, Fed economists and others have written a lot over the years analyzing the relationship among the various interest rates in terms of concepts such as the Liquidity Effect, the Fisher Effect, etc.[7] To those of the Austrian persuasion, these sorts of complex ratios and formulas are presumptively bogus. The real answer is that somebody has to buy or sell longer dated securities farther out on the curve in order to bring those other rates into line. If the market wont do it, the Fed has to, directly or indirectly. Of late, the Asian central banks have acted as enforcers, freeing the Fed from the need to bulk up its or its agent banks balance sheets.[8] We will see below, in our discussion of interest rates under the Volcker Fed, how divergent even short term rates can get when neither the Fed nor its proxies perform this function. From a technical standpoint, the
Achilles heel of the fiat money creation mechanism
is its dependence, in Phase II, on human action outside
the Feds control. This is the downside of keeping
the old pre-fiat form in place. The Fed can force
reserves into the system, because if primary dealers
dont play they dont stay primary dealers. And
the dealers (or their banks, as the case may be) have an
economic incentive to put reserves so injected to work,
because reserves dont pay interest, and thus excess
reserves, or reserves over the minimum
required, are undesirable. But it is still the case that
once inside the system, reserves need to be needed. Banks
have to want to lend, and people have to want to borrow,
before the reserves can work their way through the system
and become money. The system is like a shark that has to
keep moving, or it dies. If the Fed sets the table and
nobody shows up, it gets a deflationary contraction that
it cannot influence, let alone control. This is what the
Fed confronted in everybodys favorite oxymoron, the
Great Depression, when, as Rothbard put it:[9] Seventy years later, despite the massive substantive change thats occurred since then, this remains the Feds nightmare scenario. The more recent experience in Japan following the collapse of its bubble is a subject of intense scrutiny and dread at todays Fed.[10] Thats why Fed officials spend so much time giving speeches telling us theyre in charge and everythings okay so go ahead and borrow (create) money. Please. But speeches and spin only go so far.
How do you get people to borrow money into existence if
they dont feel like it? The same way you get people
to take anything off your hands: you price it to sell.
Here it is helpful to consider the nebulous concept of
real interest rates, as opposed to
nominal interest rates.[11] If the Fed wants to induce money creation in Phase II that it thinks would otherwise not occur, it can offer money at negative real rates, by setting the Fed funds rate below inflation expectations. This is in fact what it is doing now. At 1.5%, the Fed funds rate is well below inflation expectations. Consequently, people are literally being paid to create money. But what if people get full, and
wont borrow even if theyre paid to do so? We
quote Fed Governor Ben Bernanke, who has publicly
articulated the issue:[12] The Feds solution? Simple, says
Governor Bernanke. Well just slip into something a
little more comfortable, and let our inner self shine
through. No more reliance on pesky human action (id.): The disconnect between form and substance in the systems architecture is rivaled by the disconnect between means and ends in the Feds mission. With only the crude hydraulics of a fractional reserve system ostensibly at its command, the Fed is charged, not with maintaining a stable monetary unit, a defensible goal for a central bank that would be difficult enough (indeed, historically unprecedented) for a fiat currency, but rather with achieving maximum employment, sustainable economic growth, and price stability.[13] Its mission is thus preposterous. But instead of owning up to the limitations inherent in the Feds architecture, its officials always play along, pretending to be all knowing and all powerful. This puts them under rather severe pressure, and inevitably leads, we submit, to cheating undisclosed market intervention in furtherance of otherwise unattainable policy objectives. But we get ahead of ourselves. So now, having completed
our little refresher course in fiat money, we can turn to
consider what happened to save the system in the early
1980s. Looking back at the monetary world of
1980 is rather like viewing a Currier & Ives print.
It was a simpler time. The ongoing experiment in fiat
money and managed currencies was only nine
years old. The global monetary system was limited in
geographic scope: the Soviet empire was still a closed
system cut off from the West, and China had not yet begun
to recover from its destructive internal upheavals. A
plausible contender for the role of competing reserve
currency was scarcely a gleam in daddys eye. Financial technology was primitive. Spreadsheets were still done by hand inside the Wall Street banks, and Vydec still vied with Wang in the steno pools in the major law firms. Andy Krieger, the young derivatives trader dubbed Patient Zero who in 1987 would single-handedly short the entire money supply of New Zealand, was still studying South Asian philosophy.[14] Global OTC derivatives, had they been tracked back then by the Bank for International Settlements, would have had an aggregate notional amount of near zero. The United States was a creditor, not a debtor. The worlds largest, in fact. The term carry trade had not been invented, and the Fed would not succeed in turning the United States into The Greenspan Nation[15] and the world into a gigantic hedge fund[16] for another 24 years. But for all its quaintness in
todays terms, the monetary world of 1980 was in
grave danger. Inflation, wrote Mises early in his
career, is a monetary expansion that results in a decline
in the exchange value of money:[17] Later, writing at the height of the
German inflation, Mises described how inflationary
psychology creates a decreased demand for money. This
decreased demand is reflected in higher turnover of
money, as people hasten to get out of cash and into
something else. This is probably the closest he ever came
to embracing a concept of velocity:[18] And some thirty years after that, he
described the three main stages of inflation in a homely
metaphor:[19] By the end of the 1970s, we had reached stage two. The Appendix to the Minority Report contains a number of charts and tables that graphically depict the gravity of the situation as seen by contemporary observers. We reproduce a few below for ease of reference. The Consumer Price Index had reached worrying levels.
People were indeed becoming inflation-conscious. Contracts routinely contained inflation adjustment clauses, and housewives were beginning to buy that frying pan sooner rather than later. The bounty needed to induce people to hold dollar-denominated assets was skyrocketing, at both ends of the yield curve. Long term nominal interest rates were stratospheric, reflecting utter destruction in the bond market.
It did not help matters that real interest rates, given the high price inflation, were actually low or negative for much of the 1970s. Rates were still shocking, and the high rates were emblematic of systemic distress. Ominously, the fiat monetary system had already lost several pitched battles in its war with gold. Lacking todays price management technology, the U.S. and European monetary authorities had been forced to attempt to quell the gold price by means of open sales of physical metal throughout the preceding 18 years. The London Gold Pool of the 1960s had broken down in abject failure in March 1968, leading to the abrogation of the Bretton Woods gold exchange monetary system three years later. The U.S. Treasury gold sales of the 1970s ended in 1979, and the last of the parallel sales by the International Monetary Fund occurred on May 7, 1980. Like interest rates, and despite the
best efforts of the monetary authorities, the gold price
was soaring, hitting $850 in the afternoon London fix on
January 15, 1980. The false premise at the core of the
fiat monetary system, the conceit that paper printed by a
government bureau is money and that gold is not, was
being exposed for all to see. The very structure of the system was eroding. Membership in the Federal Reserve System was at that time elective for banks operating under state, rather than federal charters. Fed membership was expensive: member banks had to comply with the reserve ratio, and tie up funds in reserve assets that paid no interest. So new banks were being formed under state statutes, and existing members were quitting the Federal Reserve System altogether, switching their charters from federal to state and opting out of the Feds burdensome regulatory scheme.[23] The power of the central bank, the linchpin of the fiat monetary system, was waning. Something had to be done. There was still time to avert a stage three inflation, but there was no time to lose. The Making of a Legend:
Volcker the Monetarist Volcker was a public servant who had served the
government in both capitals, Washington and Wall Street.
He was a policy maker under four Republican and
Democratic Presidents and had spent years on Capitol Hill
fencing with congressional committees and lobbying for
votes. He was in Treasury when John F. Kennedy proposed
the stimulative tax cuts of the early 1960s and when
Lyndon Johnson launched the U.S. war in Indochina. Under
Nixon, he worked closely with Treasury Secretary John
Connally, an urbane Texas politician who frequently
complained about Volckers dowdy appearance.
(Connally once threatened to fire him if Volcker did not
get a haircut and buy a new suit.) / Together, Connally
and Volcker engineered the most fundamental change in the
worlds monetary system since World War II
the dismantling of the Bretton Woods agreement that had
made the U.S. dollar the stable bench mark for all
currencies. According to legend, once installed as
Chairman, Volcker quickly sized up the situation and
reoriented monetary policy to focus on the quantity
of money, rather than its price. This
famous policy shift was announced to the world in the
October 6 Record of Policy Actions of the FOMC, which
heralded:[25] And the wide swings in the monetary base were clearly inconsistent with monetarist doctrine, which prescribed a gentle and systematic reduction in the rate of increase in the monetary base until the growth rates of the money stocks, observed as indicators, came down to noninflationary values.[30] Having said that, in fairness it is not
clear that what was happening to the monetary base was
entirely within the Feds control. The problem is
that, as Rothbard points out,[31] the two
constituents of the monetary base, cash and reserves,
move in opposite directions. That is, cash in circulation
represents reduced reserves: once outside the banks, it
no longer counts as a reserve asset, and loses its
multiplier. If people decide to pull money out of their
bank accounts and hold it in the form of cash as opposed
to leaving it in the form of abstract deposits on the
banks books, this depletes reserves, turning high
powered money into chump change and initiating a rippling
contractionary process. So adjustments must be made at
the bank: aggregate deposits must shrink or reserves must
be replenished through Open Market Operations. The
contradictions inherent in our fiat money, the spawn of a
beast with the brain of a printing press and the body of
a fractional reserve banking system, are not to be
reconciled simply by focusing on the right
monetary aggregate. This increase in demand left tracks in
statistics generated by a mainstream mathematical formula
known as velocity. Velocity is a term used
to express the concept of turnover of units of money in
relation to broader measures of economic activity, like
GNP. As such, it is one of those equations without
meaning for Austrian economists. Indeed, Mises
specifically rejected velocity as a top-down explanatory
formula:[34] Back in 1914, Mises defined deflation
as the converse of inflation:[36] The resultant increase in the objective
exchange value of money found expression in a steep
decline in the rate of increase in prices tracked by the
various indexes. Costatino Bresciani-Turroni, a first
hand observer of the German inflation who later wrote the
definitive treatment of the subject, describes what
Austrian economists refer to as the crack-up
boom that was unfolding by August 1923:[38 The reduced role of the legal issue
created the necessary conditions for monetary reform, a
process that took place roughly from August through
November 1923. The reform involved the introduction of
new types of money. These were all conjurors
tricks, unbacked paper experiments issued in great
quantity and announced with great fanfare as money
with a stable value. The first of the new money
issued was in the form of Gold Treasury Bonds
and notes backed by a Gold Loan, issued
principally at the provincial and town level.
Bresciani-Turroni describes them thus:[39] In the United States of the early 1980s, the earlier stage inflation had not run its course to currency collapse. No new currency had been introduced. No grand plan had been implemented. The fiat monetary spigots were opened wide after a few short years of relative restraint, and the Fed explicitly repudiated its tight money policies in October 1982.[42] So the question remains, what accounted for this increase in the demand for fiat money? The answer appears to reside principally in two key factors identified by Richard Timberlake: deregulation, brought about by legislated structural change, and the internationalization of the U.S. currency.[43] Let us consider these in turn.
The monetary control provisions of
Title I strengthened the Fed in two ways. First, they
pulled the entire U.S. banking system under its control.
All depository institutions, not just member banks, were
now subject to reserve requirements set by the Fed.
Second, they expanded the list of eligible
collateral for the Feds Open Market
operations to include assets, such as foreign securities,
that were previously not eligible for purchase. In the
context of the implementation of conventional monetary
policy, the notion of eligible collateral is
meaningless, since fiat money is legal tender, and
requires no collateral in any event. The practical import
of this expansion of authority is that the Fed could now
pretty much monetize anything it wanted, including,
according to an unnamed senior Fed official quoted in a
2002 Financial Times (London) article, gold mines.[44] The structural
import, according to Timberlake, is that the Fed achieved
its ambition of becoming an imperial central bank:[45] The impact of this deregulation was immense. Now, for the first time, fiat checkbook money paid interest. This, and not the Feds jiggery-pokery on monetary policy, was the key to breaking the fever. That giant sucking sound throughout the 1980s was the flood of wealth into deposit accounts. Timberlake notes the accidental nature
of the rescue:[46] The precise impact of this phenomenon is difficult to measure because the Fed can only guess how much of its notes in circulation are actually circulating abroad. They do know that its a big number. The Fed's estimate as of the end of 1995 was that of the $375 billion then circulating outside the banks, between $200 and $250 billion, or well over half, was held outside the United States.[48] Aside from representing a significant
benefit for the United States -- currency used abroad
being equivalent to an interest free loan to the home
team -- the internationalization of U.S. currency
obviously makes difficult the measurement of even the
narrowest monetary aggregate, for purposes of
implementing domestic monetary policy. So we see how an increase in the demand for fiat money, brought about by a confluence of monetary policy, deregulation and market expansion, importantly aided by a collapse in commodity prices, proved sufficient to save the system in the 1980s. The gold bugs were right; Havensteins choice could not be ducked. What they didn't know was that it had in fact been made, largely by accident, and that the system had managed to stumble through Door Number One. Our immediate inquiry is therefore concluded. Two related questions remain, however. We will touch on them only briefly, as they bring us in contact with the subject matter of numerous current commentaries, posted here and elsewhere. The first question is: what explains
the extraordinary longevity of the preference for paper,
a move that has now lasted a generation. After all, as
Timberlake points out (id.): The effects of interest rate deregulation had pretty well worked their way into the system by August 7, 1987, when Alan Greenspan was anointed Fed Chairman. It hardly bears mention that the Greenspan Fed has not constantly reduced the rate of increase in monetary growth. To the contrary, the Greenspan Fed has been directly responsible for the greatest monetary and credit expansion in the history of the world. What, then, are these new "institutional" factors that kept the party going? They are the much-discussed fruit of the dramatic changes that have transformed the global financial system over the last 25 years, making the early 1980's more distant to us in practical terms than Weimar Germany was to the members of the Gold Commission. Not all are the Fed's doing. For example, it presided over (or, perhaps more accurately, adapted to) rather than directly instigated, the transformation of the global trading system into a giant vendor finance scheme in which the United States is permitted to borrow itself into oblivion for so long as foreign producers are prepared to accept payment in dollars and recycle them into dollar denominated assets.[50] In the case of others, its role was, to a greater or lesser degree, more direct. These include the rise of the capital markets and the decline of the traditional banking function; the triumph of derivatives and the relative decline in importance of underlying assets; the rise of huge pools of speculative capital able to drain or swamp markets with the click of a keystroke; the transformation of banks into a species of leveraged speculator; the mountain of debt and derivatives that now menaces the financial landscape; the proliferation of money substitutes that diminish further the control of the Fed over the money supply; and the transformation of the Fed itself from regulator to enabler in the destabilization of markets and the expansion of financial risk.[51] Still another "institutional" factor, one integrally related to the foregoing structural changes, is official sector cheating: undisclosed, direct or indirect intervention in financial and commodity markets undertaken to alter market appearances and influence the behavior of market participants. It is difficult to quantify, and virtually impossible to prove. It is even difficult to define. In a system in which even the financial exposures of a private hedge fund are effectively socialized, where does the "market" stop, and the Fed begin?[52] Wherever the line is drawn, we submit that it is not possible to understand how the demand for dollar assets has been sustained since 1987 without reference to such activity.[53] The ultimate rationalization for the
market manipulation, that it is done in order to stave
off the collapse of the dollar system and our privileged
position within it, is no doubt seen by those involved as
worthy; indeed, a patriotic calling that sanctions their
enrichment. Those to whom the ends justify the means, a
category which, truth to tell, probably includes most of
us when our financial well being is at stake, might be
inclined therefore to give the Fed and its agents a pass.
After all, the Fed's mandate is interventionist on its
face, the Fed's very existence is an affront to the
Constitution; having swallowed the elephant, why should
we now choke on the gnat? Perhaps this inclination, and
not just fear of negative career consequences, can
explain why so few will acknowledge the obvious. In any
event, the dispensation is not ours to give. In the end,
as Mises teaches in an oft-quoted passage, the market
will have its way:[54] The second and closely related question is: why are gold bugs still singing the same tired refrain? The Fed cheated the hangman in the 1980's; why can't it just keep doing it, wrong-footing those gloomy Guses in perpetuity? In this essay, we have attempted to lay out in some detail the confluence of factors that came together to save the system in the 1980s. We think it clear from this exercise that this was a one-off event, an historical accident that could not be repeated even if there were an identical threat, a common understanding of the nature of that threat, and the political will to implement a solution. Which of the indicated policy precedents would be open to us, even if we could satisfy the foregoing conditions? Deregulate? Clearly not; been there, done that. Hike rates to historic highs in real terms? No way. We gambol in the shadow of Debt Mountain. If the Fed were to raise the Fed funds rate even to within spitting distance of a positive real rate of interest, it would risk an avalanche of defaults, threatening economic and political upheaval. Expand the market for dollars? Get real. Just how do you expand a saturated market? The challenge now is rather to ward off blowback of the big foreign dollar float. How about rigging commodity prices? Now were getting somewhere. Trouble is, we cant rig them all, and we cant keep it up forever, even for the ones we can rig. Sooner or later, the law of supply and demand in the marketplace for real things will trump the price management effected in the markets for paper derivatives. No, the die is cast: we shall have the catastrophe. Our fiat monetary system got a reprieve in the 1980's, not a deliverance. All that has happened since, with the fantastic mispricing of credit the Greenspan Fed has engineered, and the massive global malinvestment this has engendered, is that the dimensions of the unraveling have become more dire. Mises called this one too:[55] With respect to the form the denouement will take, much has been written within the gold community on the subject of whether we face hyperinflation or deflationary depression as the prelude to monetary collapse. Both sides of the debate appear to accept the premise that whatever may transpire will bear a linear relationship to what now exists. The disagreement centers on the direction the line will go. But today's markets are fully linked by derivatives and technology, and they are patrolled by wolf packs of large, leveraged speculators not noted for their patient outlook. So it seems likely that the terminal monetary crisis will unfold on virtually an instantaneous and discontinuous basis, once the fog of statistical deceit and false market cues begins to lift and a clear trend either way becomes evident. We are not likely to enjoy the luxury of observing either a deflation or an inflation unfold in the fullness of time, but rather, just as Mises foretold, a final and total catastrophe of our fiat monetary system. All we can hope is that once the curtain falls on the current system, the wisdom in the gold bugs' submissions to the Gold Commission will finally find a receptive audience. August 21, 2004 1. Minority Report, page 283. 2. Ludwig von Mises, The Theory of Money and Credit (LibertyClassics Edition, 1981), p. 458. 3. Sean Corrigan of Sage Capital, a practicing Austrian, has expressed doubts whether the traditional formulation of the Feds role in the creation of money applies under todays institutional circumstances. He notes, among other things, that bidding for reserves occurs on a post-hoc basis; that is, banks do their lending and borrowing, and work out over the course of the two week maintenance period what they need in reserves and then go bid for the balance retrospectively, and that banks today are more on a BIS-style capital standard than subject to meaningful reserve restraints. Fair point. As a result of the structural changes that have occurred in the system since 1980, noted later in this essay, the practical significance of the reserve creation activity summarized below has been radically diminished, even though there remains a tacit agreement among the Fed, market participants and commentators to continue the pretence. As James Grant points out in the April 9, 2004, edition of Grants Interest Rate Observer, less than 4% of the broadly defined money supply is now subject to reserve requirements. However, as our focus is the early 1980s, before deregulation and technology had wrested control over the creation of money from the monetary authorities, we rationalize that current theory is at least reasonably consonant with early 1980s practice. 4. As of August 15, 2004, the primary dealers were: ABN AMRO Bank, N.V., New York Branch 5. See Murray N. Rothbard, The Mystery of Banking (Richardson & Snyder, 1983), ch. XI (www.mises.org/mysteryofbanking/mysteryofbanking.pdf). 6. The components of the monetary aggregates are summarized from Monetary Trends, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, June 2004. 7. See, e.g., Daniel L. Thornton, The Effect of Monetary Policy on Short-Term Interest Rates (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 1988) (http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/88/05/Interest_May_Jun1988.pdf). 8. This phenomenon is discussed in detail in the April 9, 2004, edition of Grants Interest Rate Observer. 9. Rothbard, op. cit., p. 145. 10. See, e.g., Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 729, June 2002, Preventing Deflation: Lessons from Japan's Experience in the 1990s (www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/2002/729/default.htm). In concluding that ...when inflation and interest rates have fallen close to zero, and the risk of deflation is high, stimulus -- both monetary and fiscal -- should go beyond the levels conventionally implied by baseline forecasts of future inflation and economic activity, this paper amplified the January FOMC discussion cited in note 10 and prefigured Governor Bernakes November remarks cited in the same note. 11. Sidney Homer and Richard Sylla, A History of Interest Rates (Rutgers University Press, 3rd ed. rev., 1996), p.429. 12. Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke before the National Economists Club, Washington, D.C., November 21, 2002: Deflation: Making Sure "It" Doesn't Happen Here (www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002/20021121/default.htm). Governor Bernanke was not just out on a frolic of his own. See also the (heavily redacted; full minutes are not released until five years after the event) Minutes of the FOMC, January 29-30, 2002, in which the following curious passage appears:
A March 25, 2002 Financial Times article by Peronet Despeignes quoted an unnamed senior Fed official who attended the meeting as stating that the term unconventional means was commonly understood by academics, and that the Fed could theoretically buy anything to pump money into the system, including state and local debt, real estate and gold minesany asset. It does not appear that this purchase of any asset can be reconciled with the Feds statutory authority. Perhaps that is why the senior official in the FT article chose to remain nameless, and no such specific brainstorming can be found in Governor Bernankes remarks. 13. See Remarks by Chairman Alan Greenspan at the Annual Dinner and Francis Boyer Lecture of The American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C., December 5, 1996 (www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/19961205.htm). 14. Frank Partnoy, Infectious Greed (Henry Holt & Co., 2003), p. 18. 15. Dan Chung and Zachary Karabell, The Greenspan Nation, The Wall Street Journal, August 12, 2004. 16. Stephen Roach, The World's Biggest Hedge Fund, Morgan Stanley Research (New York), July 19, 2004. 17. Mises, Theory of Money and Credit, p. 272. 18. Mises, Stabilization of the Monetary UnitFrom the Viewpoint of Theory (monograph,1923) (www.mises.org/manipulation/section1.asp). 19. Mises, Theory of Money and Credit, p. 459. 20. See, e.g., Market Observations, Contrary Investor.com, June 15, 2000 (www.contraryinvestor.com/moarchive2000/mo061500.htm). 21. Mises, Theory of Money and Credit, p. 460. 22. William Greider, Secrets of the Temple (Simon & Schuster, 1989), p. 380. 23. See, e.g., John T. Rove, An Analysis of Federal Reserve System Attrition Since 1960 (Federal Reserve Staff Study 93, 1977). 24. Greider, op. cit., p. 68. 25. Cited in Richard Timberlake, Monetary Policy in the United States (University of Chicago Press, 1993), p. 348. 26. M.A. Akhtar, Understanding Open Market Operations, Public Information Department, FRBNY, 1977, p. 7 (www.ny.frb.org/education/addpub/pdf/acknow.pdf). 27. Greider, op. cit., p. 501. 28. These aggregates are not identical in composition to todays aggregates, as defined supra. However, they are close enough for our purposes. 29. Timberlake, op. cit., p. 356. 30. Timberlake, op. cit., p. 358. 32. Greider, op. cit., p. 507. 33. Federal Reserve Bulletin 69, August 1983, p. 619, cited in Timberlake, op. cit., p. 379. 34. Mises, Human Action, A Treatise on Economics (Fox & Wilkes, 4th rev. ed., 1963), p 399. 35. Ibid., p. 400. 36. Mises, Theory of Money and Credit, p. 272. 37. Just how historically anomalous these levels of real rates were can be seen in the following table from Homer and Sylla, op. cit., p. 430.(Sorry this is missing.jb.editor) 38. Costantino Bresciani-Turroni, The Economics of Inflation (Augustus M. Kelley, 3rd ed., 1968), p. 347. 39. Ibid., p. 344. 40. Ibid., pp 347-348. 41. Ibid., p. 348. 42. Timberlake, op. cit., p. 360. 43. Timberlake, op. cit., ch. 25. 44. See Note 10. DIDMCA did not in fact authorize the purchase of real estate and gold mines, but the quote attributed to the senior Fed official, if true, would indicate that the FOMC doesnt know it. 45. Timberlake, op. cit., pp. 371, 374. 46. Ibid., p. 382. 47. Ibid., p. 377. 48. See Richard A. Porter and Ruth A. Judson,
The Location of U.S. Currency: How Much Is
Abroad? Federal Reserve Bulletin, October
1996 49. Mark Faber, A President Bush Economic
Boom?, July 8, 2004 50. For a useful analysis of the imbalances in the global trading system, see Richard Duncan, The Dollar Crisis (John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte Ltd, 2003). 51. A number of these structural changes are discussed
in Peter Warburton, Debt & Delusion (Penguin
Press, 1999), recently reviewed by Robert Blumen at http://mises.org/fullstory.aspx?control=1579.
52. The New York Fed orchestrated, but did not directly fund, the bailout of Long Term Capital Management. See Roger Lowenstein, When Genius Failed (Fourth Estate/HarperCollins, 2001). For market participants whose livelihoods depend on correct assessments of how far they can push the house in the game of moral hazard it was a distinction without a difference. 53. It is worth recalling what appears to be the
origin of the contemporary stripe of market intervention.
Fittingly, it remains ambiguous as to whence directed and
how effected, and thus where the line between official
and private action can be drawn. The setting
was the October 1987 crash. Sometime after 11:20 on the
morning of October 20, just when all seemed lost, the
Major Market Index, an obscure stock index futures
contract on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange, suddenly
soared heavenward. Tim Metz, the reporter who covered the
Crash of 1987 for The Wall Street Journal and
later expanded his reportage in Black Monday (Dow
Jones, 1988) described it as follows (pp. 217-218): In what may be the last time a Dow Jones publication
would give voice to a financial market conspiracy
theory, Metz attributed what happened to human
intervention (p.210): 54. Mises, Human Action, p. 572. 55. Mises, Theory of Money and Credit, p. 404. |